The social cost of lobbying over climate policy

Domestic political processes shape climate policy. In particular, there is increasing concern about the role of political lobbying over climate policy. This paper examines how lobbying spending on the Waxman–Markey bill, the most prominent and promising United States climate regulation so far, altered its likelihood of being implemented. We combine data from comprehensive United States lobbying records with an empirical method for forecasting the policy’s effect on the value of publicly listed firms. Our statistical analysis suggests that lobbying by firms expecting losses from the policy was more effective than lobbying by firms expecting gains. Interpreting this finding through a game-theoretic model, we calculate that lobbying lowered the probability of enacting the Waxman–Markey bill by 13 percentage points, representing an expected social cost of US$60 billion (in 2018 US dollars). Our findings also suggest how future climate policy proposals can be designed to be more robust to political opposition.Political interests play a key role in the passage of climate policy. This study quantifies that political lobbying reduced the probability of enacting the Waxman–Markey bill in the United States by 13 percentage points, representing US$60 billion in expected climate damages.

[1]  Judith A. Layzer Open for Business: Conservatives' Opposition to Environmental Regulation , 2012 .

[2]  J. Perloff,et al.  Distributing Pollution Rights in Cap-and-Trade Programs: Are Outcomes Independent of Allocation? , 2008, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[3]  Johannes Urpelainen,et al.  Electric Utilities and American Climate Policy: Lobbying by Expected Winners and Losers , 2014 .

[4]  W. Montgomery,et al.  Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs" Journal of Economic Theory , 1972 .

[5]  Beth L. Leech,et al.  Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why , 2009 .

[6]  S. Kamieniecki Corporate America and Environmental Policy: How Often Does Business Get Its Way? , 2006 .

[7]  C. Downie Business actors, political resistance, and strategies for policymakers , 2017 .

[8]  W. Nordhaus Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches , 2014, Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists.

[9]  R. Hahn,et al.  The Effect of Allowance Allocations on Cap-and-Trade System Performance , 2010, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[10]  Antje Strauss,et al.  Environment And Statecraft The Strategy Of Environmental Treaty Making , 2016 .

[11]  Gilbert E. Metcalf,et al.  Behavioral and Distributional Effects of Environmental Policy , 2001 .

[12]  R. Tollison,et al.  Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society , 1982 .

[13]  Scott Barrett,et al.  Environment and Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental Treaty‐making , 2003 .

[14]  Johannes Urpelainen,et al.  How do Competing Interest Groups Influence Environmental Policy? The Case of Renewable Electricity in Industrialized Democracies, 1989–2007 , 2013 .

[15]  Jianqing Fan,et al.  Local polynomial modelling and its applications , 1994 .

[16]  G. Becker,et al.  A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence , 1983 .

[17]  W. Nordhaus A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies , 2008 .

[18]  Elhanan Helpman,et al.  Protection for Sale , 1992 .

[19]  A. Gullberg Lobbying friends and foes in climate policy: The case of business and environmental interest groups in the European Union , 2008 .

[20]  J. Grumbach Polluting industries as climate protagonists: cap and trade and the problem of business preferences , 2015, Business and Politics.

[21]  G. Tullock Efficient Rent Seeking , 2001 .

[22]  Alan V. Deardorff,et al.  Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy , 2006, American Political Science Review.

[23]  T. Persson Economic Policy and Special Interest Politics , 1998 .

[24]  Justin Wolfers,et al.  Interpreting Prediction Market Prices as Probabilities , 2006 .

[25]  A. Gullberg Rational lobbying and EU climate policy , 2008 .

[26]  J. Hirshleifer Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs. difference models of relative success , 1989 .

[27]  T. Skocpol NAMING THE PROBLEM What It Will Take to Counter Extremism and Engage Americans in the Fight against Global Warming , 2013 .

[28]  P. Bernhagen Business and International Environmental Agreements: Domestic Sources of Participation and Compliance by Advanced Industrialized Democracies , 2008, Global Environmental Politics.

[29]  Kyle C. Meng,et al.  Using a Free Permit Rule to Forecast the Marginal Abatement Cost of Proposed Climate Policy , 2016 .

[30]  Robert J. Brulle The climate lobby: a sectoral analysis of lobbying spending on climate change in the USA, 2000 to 2016 , 2018, Climatic Change.

[31]  Sidney C. Sufrin,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. , 1966 .

[32]  T. Hurley Rent dissipation and efficiency in a contest with asymmetric valuations , 1998 .

[33]  J. Wolfers,et al.  How Prediction Markets Can Save Event Studies , 2008, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[34]  K. Kang,et al.  Policy Influence and Private Returns from Lobbying in the Energy Sector , 2016 .

[35]  N. Stern The Economics of Climate Change: Implications of Climate Change for Development , 2007 .

[36]  M. Delmas,et al.  Corporate Environmental Performance and Lobbying , 2015 .

[37]  The Effect of Allowance Allocations on Cap-and-Trade System Performance , 2010, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[38]  Elhanan Helpman,et al.  The Politics of Free Trade Agreements , 1993 .

[39]  Roger D. Congleton,et al.  Forty Years of Research on Rent Seeking: An Overview , 2008 .

[40]  Martin Browning,et al.  Income and Outcomes: A Structural Model of Intrahousehold Allocation , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[41]  David G. Victor,et al.  Global Warming Gridlock: Creating More Effective Strategies for Protecting the Planet , 2011 .