A Network Approach to Public Goods

An economy can be thought of as a network in which the nodes are agents and links among them represent heterogeneous opportunities for exchange or cooperation. This paper argues that studying properties of such a network -- how dense it is, how "central" various agents are in it -- yields insights about issues such as the efficiency and fragility of an economic system, as well as its market outcomes. We develop this conceptual point in a model of a public goods economy: one in which each agent can incur a private cost to take an action -- e.g., reducing pollution -- that creates nonrival but heterogeneous benefits for others. The network we study is a directed, weighted graph in which an edge from agent i to agent j captures the marginal benefits i can provide to j, at the current action profile, as i increases his public good provision. We find that when the largest eigenvalue of this network differs from one there are Pareto inefficiencies. The largest eigenvalue can be interpreted in terms of cycles in the benefits network (e.g., X can help Y, who can help Z, who can help X). These are critical to finding a Pareto improvement on a given outcome, and the network's largest eigenvalue quantifies the marginal returns available from exploiting such cycles. Building on the eigenvalue result, we propose a simple algorithm to find the players who are essential to a negotiation -- in the sense that without their participation, there is no Pareto improvement on the status quo. They are the ones whose removal causes a sufficiently large disruption of cycles in the benefits network, as measured by the decrease in its largest eigenvalue. Since Wicksell [1896] and Lindahl [1919] it has been recognized that a system of personalized taxes and subsidies can incentivize efficient public good provision. Lindahl outcomes are analogues of Walrasian market allocations in which the taxes and subsidies internalize all the externalities. Our main result characterizes the Lindahl outcomes in terms of the same marginal benefits matrix we use to diagnose inefficiencies. A nonzero action profile is a Lindahl outcome if and only if it is an eigenvector centrality action profile for the marginal benefits matrix. At such an action profile, the agents contribute in proportion to how much they value the efforts of those who help them. We deduce two main interpretable consequences from this characterization. First, it is the benefits an agent receives, rather than those he can confer, that determine his level of effort. Second, the players contributing the most are those who are most "central" in the benefits network, in the sense that they receive strong direct and indirect benefit flows from others. As Samuelson [1954] discusses, Lindahl taxes and subsidies often cannot be directly implemented in practice because they require a planner to know agents' utility functions. Nevertheless, Lindahl outcomes turn out to play a distinguished role in several strategic settings. First: any implementable, continuous social choice correspondence that is Pareto efficient and individually rational must contain all the Lindahl outcomes Hurwicz [1979a, 1979b], and Hurwicz, Maskin, and Postlewaite [1995]). Second the Lindahl outcomes are the equilibrium outcomes of a natural non-cooperative bargaining game among the n agents (Dávila, Eeckhout, and Martinelli [2009] and Penta [2011]). Finally, the Lindahl outcomes are robust to coalitional deviations (Aumann [1959], Shapley and Shubik [1969], Foley [1970]). Ballester et al [2006] as well as Bramoullé et al [2011] have found relationships between the Nash equilibria of games and the spectral properties of an interaction network under the assumption of linear best responses. In contrast, we study efficiency and market outcomes and do not require functional form assumptions.

[1]  Alan T. Peacock,et al.  Classics in the theory of public finance , 1959 .

[2]  H. Varian,et al.  On the private provision of public goods , 1986 .

[3]  G. Debreu,et al.  Nonnegative Square Matrices , 1953 .

[4]  Y. Zenou,et al.  Local and Consistent Centrality Measures in Networks , 2014 .

[5]  Ye Du,et al.  Competitive economy as a ranking device over networks , 2015, Games Econ. Behav..

[6]  T. Groves,et al.  Optimal Allocation of Public Goods: A Solution to the 'Free Rider Problem' , 1977 .

[7]  P. Perkins A theorem on regular matrices. , 1961 .

[8]  Antoni Calvó-Armengol,et al.  Centre De Referència En Economia Analítica Barcelona Economics Working Paper Series Working Paper Nº 178 Who's Who in Networks. Wanted: the Key Player Who's Who in Networks. Wanted: the Key Player Barcelona Economics Wp Nº 178 , 2022 .

[9]  E. Maskin Nash Equilibrium and Welfare Optimality , 1999 .

[10]  M. Whinston,et al.  Coalition-Proof Nash Equilibria I. Concepts , 1987 .

[11]  Charles R. Johnson,et al.  On Matrices with Perron–Frobenius Properties and Some Negative Entries , 2004 .

[12]  Debraj Ray,et al.  Group Formation in Risk-Sharing Arrangements , 2003 .

[13]  Oliver Baetz,et al.  Social Activity and Network Formation , 2015 .

[14]  P. Bonacich Power and Centrality: A Family of Measures , 1987, American Journal of Sociology.

[15]  Chris Shannon Determinacy and Indeterminacy of Equilibria , 2006 .

[16]  K. Arrow,et al.  The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics , 2020 .

[17]  Duncan K. Foley,et al.  Lindahl's Solution and the Core of an Economy with Public Goods , 1970 .

[18]  Matthew O. Jackson,et al.  A crash course in implementation theory , 2001, Soc. Choice Welf..

[19]  L. Hurwicz Outcome Functions Yielding Walrasian and Lindahl Allocations at Nash Equilibrium Points , 1979 .

[20]  Carl D. Meyer,et al.  Matrix Analysis and Applied Linear Algebra , 2000 .

[21]  M. Kendall Further contributions to the theory of paired comparisons , 1955 .

[22]  Matthew Elliott,et al.  A network approach to public goods , 2013, EC.

[23]  Multilateral bargaining and Walrasian equilibrium , 2011 .

[24]  Navin Kartik,et al.  Implementation with Evidence , 2012 .

[25]  Phillip Bonacich,et al.  Simultaneous group and individual centralities , 1991 .

[26]  Oscar Volij,et al.  The Measurement of Intellectual Influence , 2002 .

[27]  Muhamet Yildiz Walrasian bargaining , 2003, Games Econ. Behav..

[28]  Jan Eeckhout,et al.  Competitive bargaining equilibrium , 2008, J. Econ. Theory.

[29]  J. H. Wilkinson The algebraic eigenvalue problem , 1966 .

[30]  Leonid Hurwicz,et al.  On allocations attainable through Nash equilibria , 1979 .

[31]  Vasco M. Carvalho,et al.  The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations , 2011 .

[32]  Benjamin Golub,et al.  The Leverage of Weak Ties How Linking Groups Affects Inequality ∗ , 2012 .

[33]  Daron Acemoglu,et al.  State Capacity and Economic Development: A Network Approach , 2014 .

[34]  Milan Horniacek The approximation of a strong perfect equilibrium in a discounted supergame , 1996 .

[35]  R. Kranton,et al.  Strategic Interaction and Networks , 2010 .

[36]  A. Galeotti,et al.  The Law of the Few , 2010 .

[37]  Pawan Kumar,et al.  Notice of Violation of IEEE Publication Principles The Anatomy of a Large-Scale Hyper Textual Web Search Engine , 2009 .

[38]  Joel E. Cohen,et al.  Derivatives of the spectral radius as a function of non-negative matrix elements , 1978, Mathematical Proceedings of the Cambridge Philosophical Society.

[39]  Guoqiang Tian Continuous and Feasible Implementation of Rational-Expectations Lindahl Allocations , 1996 .

[40]  Nizar Allouch,et al.  On the Private Provision of Public Goods on Networks , 2012, J. Econ. Theory.

[41]  Amy Nicole Langville,et al.  Google's PageRank and beyond - the science of search engine rankings , 2006 .

[42]  Leo Katz,et al.  A new status index derived from sociometric analysis , 1953 .

[43]  Noah E. Friedkin,et al.  Theoretical Foundations for Centrality Measures , 1991, American Journal of Sociology.

[45]  Ariel Rubinstein,et al.  Strong perfect equilibrium in supergames , 1980 .

[46]  Ulrike von Luxburg,et al.  A tutorial on spectral clustering , 2007, Stat. Comput..

[47]  D. Noutsos,et al.  On Perron–Frobenius property of matrices having some negative entries☆ , 2006 .

[48]  Sergey Brin,et al.  The Anatomy of a Large-Scale Hypertextual Web Search Engine , 1998, Comput. Networks.

[49]  P. Samuelson The Pure Theory of Public Expanditure , 1954 .

[50]  K. Arrow “ The Organization of Economic Activity : Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market versus Non-market Allocation ” , 1969 .

[51]  K. Wicksell A New Principle of Just Taxation , 1958 .

[52]  Teh-Hsing Wei,et al.  The algebraic foundations of ranking theory , 1952 .

[53]  Yann Bramoullé,et al.  Public goods in networks , 2007, J. Econ. Theory.

[54]  Joan de Martí,et al.  Communication and influence , 2015 .

[55]  Moshe Tennenholtz,et al.  Ranking systems: the PageRank axioms , 2005, EC '05.

[56]  J. Dávila,et al.  Bargaining over Public Goods , 2009 .

[57]  R. Aumann,et al.  VON NEUMANN-MORGENSTERN SOLUTIONS TO COOPERATIVE GAMES WITHOUT SIDE PAYMENTS , 1960, Classics in Game Theory.

[58]  E. Lindahl Just Taxation—A Positive Solution , 1958 .

[59]  Yves Zenou,et al.  Peer Effects and Social Networks in Education , 2008 .

[60]  Carl D. Meyer,et al.  On the structure of stochastic matrices with a subdominant eigenvalue near 1 , 1998 .

[61]  M. Ostrovsky,et al.  Stability and Competitive Equilibrium in Trading Networks , 2013, Journal of Political Economy.

[62]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  Expressive negotiation over donations to charities , 2004, EC '04.

[63]  Mohammad Mahdian,et al.  Charity auctions on social networks , 2008, SODA '08.

[64]  L. Shapley,et al.  On the Core of an Economic System with Externalities , 1969 .