Substitution and Stratification: The Interplay between Dyadic and Systemic Proximity in Global Trade, 1993–2005

This article examines the interplay of homophily (similarity breeds connection) at two levels in international trade—dyadic similarity (geographic, political, and cultural proximity) and systemic similarity (structural equivalence and world-system status). First, there is a substitution effect between dyadic homophily and systemic homophily from structural equivalence. Both types of homophily generate favorable social structure that facilitates international trade. The existence of structural equivalence lessens the dependence of bilateral trade on dyadic homophily. Second, there is a stratification effect of world-system status on dyadic homophily. Geographic homophily matters the most for bilateral trade between two noncore countries, while political and cultural homophily is the most influential for trade between a core country and a noncore country. These two findings have important implications. The substitution effect of structural equivalence prevents international trade from complete fragmentation along geographic, political, and cultural lines, while the stratification effect of world-system status reveals unequal capacity across countries to overcome the structural constraints imposed by dyadic homophily.

[1]  Stanley Wasserman,et al.  Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications , 1994, Structural analysis in the social sciences.

[2]  B. Uzzi,et al.  The Sources and Consequences of Embeddedness for the Economic Performance of Organizations: The Network Effect , 1996 .

[3]  Martin G. Everett,et al.  Models of core/periphery structures , 2000, Soc. Networks.

[4]  Jeffrey M. Woodbridge Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data , 2002 .

[5]  Helen V. Milner,et al.  Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries , 2005, International Organization.

[6]  S. Borgatti,et al.  Regular equivalence: general theory , 1994 .

[7]  K. Reitz,et al.  Graph and Semigroup Homomorphisms on Networks of Relations , 1983 .

[8]  David Hummels Transportation Costs and International Trade in the Second Era of Globalization , 2007 .

[9]  Ronald Robinson,et al.  The imperialism of decolonization , 1994 .

[10]  Mark S. Granovetter Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness , 1985, American Journal of Sociology.

[11]  P. Ingram,et al.  Spanning the Institutional Abyss: The Intergovernmental Network and the Governance of Foreign Direct Investment1 , 2013, American Journal of Sociology.

[12]  N. Bandelj Embedded Economies: Social Relations as Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in Central and Eastern Europe , 2002 .

[13]  Bart Bonikowski Cross-national interaction and cultural similarity: A relational analysis , 2010 .

[14]  Sangmoon Kim,et al.  A Longitudinal Analysis of Globalization and Regionalization in International Trade: A Social Network Approach , 2002 .

[15]  Ronald S. Burt,et al.  Positions in Networks , 1976 .

[16]  Min Zhou,et al.  The cohesion effect of structural equivalence on global bilateral trade, 1948–2000 , 2012 .

[17]  Viviana A. Zelizer,et al.  Beyond the polemics on the market: Establishing a theoretical and empirical agenda , 1988 .

[18]  James E. Rauch,et al.  Networks Versus Markets in International Trade , 1996 .

[19]  Dieter Schumacher,et al.  Using the gravity equation to differentiate among alternative theories of trade: another look , 2007 .

[20]  Rob Clark,et al.  A New Trichotomous Measure of World-system Position Using the International Trade Network , 2009 .

[21]  Min Zhou Multidimensionality and Gravity in Global Trade, 1950-2000 , 2010 .

[22]  Ronald L. Breiger,et al.  Structures of Economic Interdependence among Nations , 1982 .

[23]  E. Kick,et al.  Structural Position in the World System and Economic Growth, 1955-1970: A Multiple-Network Analysis of Transnational Interactions , 1979, American Journal of Sociology.

[24]  J. Bergstrand The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence , 1985 .

[25]  James E. Anderson A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation , 1979 .

[26]  Johan Galtung,et al.  A Structural Theory of Imperialism , 1971 .

[27]  B. Uzzi,et al.  Embeddedness in the Making of Financial Capital: How Social Relations and Networks Benefit Firms Seeking Financing , 1999, The New Economic Sociology.

[28]  Jeffrey A. Frankel,et al.  The Regionalization Of The World Economy , 1997 .

[29]  David A. Smith,et al.  Structure and Dynamics of the Global Economy: Network Analysis of International Trade 1965–1980 , 1992 .

[30]  M. McPherson,et al.  Birds of a Feather: Homophily in Social Networks , 2001 .

[31]  W. Beckerman,et al.  Distance and the pattern of intra-European trade , 1956 .

[32]  Mark Neal,et al.  The Culture Factor: Cross-National Management and the Foreign Venture , 1998 .

[33]  John F. Veiga,et al.  Acculturation in Acquired Organizations: A Force-Field Perspective , 1994 .

[34]  Min Zhou Intensification of geo-cultural homophily in global trade: Evidence from the gravity model , 2011 .

[35]  Samuel Leinhardt,et al.  Roles and Positions: A Critique and Extension of the Blockmodeling Approach , 1983 .

[36]  William J. Dixon,et al.  Political Similarity and American Foreign Trade Patterns , 1993 .

[37]  Edward E. Leamer,et al.  The Economic Geography of the Internet Age , 2001 .

[38]  Helen V. Milner,et al.  Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade , 2000, American Political Science Review.

[39]  Steven E. Finkel,et al.  Causal Analysis With Panel Data , 1995, SAGE Research Methods Foundations.

[40]  Mark Neal,et al.  The Culture Factor , 1998 .

[41]  A. Venables,et al.  The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade , 1999 .

[42]  A. Rose,et al.  Which International Institutions Promote International Trade? , 2003 .

[43]  Bruce Russett,et al.  Democratic Trading Partners: The Liberal Connection, 1962-1989 , 1998, The Journal of Politics.

[44]  H. White,et al.  “Structural Equivalence of Individuals in Social Networks” , 2022, The SAGE Encyclopedia of Research Design.

[45]  David Krackhardt,et al.  Sensitivity of MRQAP Tests to Collinearity and Autocorrelation Conditions , 2007, Psychometrika.

[46]  Marc L. Busch,et al.  The Intergovernmental Network of World Trade: IGO Connectedness, Governance, and Embeddedness1 , 2005, American Journal of Sociology.

[47]  David Krackhardt,et al.  PREDICTING WITH NETWORKS: NONPARAMETRIC MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS OF DYADIC DATA * , 1988 .

[48]  S. Steiber The World System and World Trade: an Empirical Exploration of Conceptual Conflicts , 1978 .

[49]  Matthew C. Mahutga The Persistence of Structural Inequality?: A Network Analysis of International Trade, 1965-2000 , 2006 .

[50]  J. Frankel Regional Trading Blocs in the world economic system, reseñado por Antonio Ortiz-Mena L.N. , 1997 .

[51]  John Skvoretz,et al.  Embedded Trade: A Third‐Party Effect , 2010 .

[52]  J. O'neal,et al.  The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950–1985 , 1997 .

[53]  I. Wallerstein,et al.  The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century , 1976 .

[54]  R. Vanrossem,et al.  The world system paradigm as general theory of development : A cross-national test , 1996 .

[55]  C. Halaby,et al.  Panel Models in Sociological Research: Theory into Practice , 2004 .