Coevolutionary Agricultural Development

Doubts about the appropriateness of models of economic development-about their ability to predict in advance or describe in retrospect the consequences of their own prescriptions for growth-have been increasing over the past decade.' While much of this discontent has centered on broad issues such as economic and political inequality, agricultural development-whether neglected or not-has rarely followed the path established for it by economic planners. Many of agriculture's detours and dead ends have been explored needlessly, because economic prescriptions have been incongruous with ecological knowledge.2 My own research has recently emphasized development failure and environmental degradation in the Amazon, a manenvironment interaction with analogues in tropical rain forest ecosystems in Central America, Africa, and Asia.3 Other sociosystemecosystem combinations, notably nomadic herding in the vast semidesert regions of Africa and subsistence agriculture in the mountainous regions of South America and South and Southeast Asia, are also temporarily accommodating larger populations through environmental degradation rather than through improved forms of interaction. The coevolutionary perspective outlined in this paper provides a linkage between economic and ecological paradigms. The perspective emphasizes how man's agricultural activities modify the ecosystem and how the ecosystem's responses provide cause for subsequent individual action and social organization. A linkage is quite different from a grand synthesis of previously incongruous paradigms. Through a linkage, each discipline enriches the other because of their differences. Neither discipline must abandon its past. Eventually, however, new emphases and approaches arise because of the enrichment. A similar linkage between anthropology and ecology produced the fertile subdiscipline of cultural ecology. This paper outlines some of the differences in economic and ecological thinking, the advantages of enrichment,

[1]  C. Pearson,et al.  Environment, North and South : an economic interpretation , 1978 .

[2]  A. Alchian Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory , 1950, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  P. Ehrlich Environmental disruption: implications for the social sciences , 1981 .

[4]  Y. Hayami,et al.  Agricultural Development: An International Perspective. , 1972 .

[5]  J. Tobin,et al.  Is growth obsolete , 1973 .

[6]  E. Odum The strategy of ecosystem development. , 1969, Science.

[7]  Harold Francis Blum,et al.  Time's Arrow and Evolution , 1951, The Yale Journal of Biology and Medicine.

[8]  R. G. Cummings,et al.  Thermodynamic and Economic Concepts as Related to Resource-Use Policies , 1980 .

[9]  J. Perkins,et al.  Insects, Experts, and the Insecticide Crisis: The Quest for New Pest Management Strategies , 1982 .

[10]  John W. Kendrick,et al.  Productivity Trends in the United States. , 1962 .

[11]  D. Meadows,et al.  The Limits to Growth , 2018, Green Planet Blues.

[12]  R. Heilbroner An inquiry into the human prospect : updated and reconsidered for the 1980s , 1980 .

[13]  Richard B. Norgaard,et al.  Sociosystem and ecosystem coevolution in the amazon , 1981 .

[14]  Daniel Sommer Robinson,et al.  The Idea Of Progress , 1920 .

[15]  The Evaluation of Natural Resource Adequacy: Elusive Quest or Frontier of Economic Analysis? , 1980 .

[16]  E. F. Denison,et al.  The Sources of Economic Growth in the United States , 1962 .

[17]  T. Schultz The Declining Economic Importance of Agricultural Land , 1951 .

[18]  W. H. Patrick,et al.  Nitrogen Fixation in Flooded Soil Systems, A Review , 1980 .

[19]  Scarcity and Growth: How Does It Look Today? , 1975 .

[20]  Richard Schlegel,et al.  The Entropy Law and the Economic Process , 1973 .

[21]  Environmental amenity rights, transactions costs, and technological change , 1974 .

[22]  Stephen H. Schneider,et al.  The Genesis Strategy , 1976 .

[23]  Sidney G. Winter,et al.  Satisficing, Selection, and the Innovating Remnant , 1971 .