Transmission errors and influence maximization in the voter model

In this paper we analyze the effects of mistakes in opinion propagation in the voter model on strategic influence maximization. We provide numerical results and analytical arguments to show that generally two regimes exist for optimal opinion control: a regime of low transmission errors in which influence maximizers should focus on hub nodes and a large-error regime in which influence maximizers should focus on low-degree nodes. We also develop a degree-based mean-field theory and apply it to random networks with bimodal degree distribution, finding that analytical results for the dependence of regimes on parameters qualitatively agree with numerical results for scale-free networks. We generally find that the regime of optimal hub control is the larger, the more heterogeneous the social network and the smaller the more resources both available to the influencers.

[1]  Markus Brede,et al.  Effects of Time Horizons on Influence Maximization in the Voter Dynamics , 2018, J. Complex Networks.

[2]  M. Mobilia Does a single zealot affect an infinite group of voters? , 2003, Physical review letters.

[3]  Marco Alberto Javarone,et al.  Network strategies in election campaigns , 2013, 1311.5933.

[4]  Flávio L. Pinheiro,et al.  When to target hubs? Strategic Diffusion in Complex Networks , 2017, ArXiv.

[5]  Michael Kearns,et al.  Competitive contagion in networks , 2019, Games Econ. Behav..

[6]  Christian Borgs,et al.  Maximizing Social Influence in Nearly Optimal Time , 2012, SODA.

[7]  Vittorio Loreto,et al.  Opinion dynamics: models, extensions and external effects , 2016, Participatory Sensing, Opinions and Collective Awareness.

[8]  S. S. Ravi,et al.  Controlling opinion propagation in online networks , 2013, Comput. Networks.

[9]  S. Redner,et al.  On the role of zealotry in the voter model , 2007 .

[10]  Éva Tardos,et al.  Maximizing the Spread of Influence through a Social Network , 2015, Theory Comput..

[11]  Matthew Richardson,et al.  Mining the network value of customers , 2001, KDD '01.

[12]  R. Holley,et al.  Ergodic Theorems for Weakly Interacting Infinite Systems and the Voter Model , 1975 .

[13]  Hernán A. Makse,et al.  Influence maximization in complex networks through optimal percolation , 2015, Nature.

[14]  Markus Brede,et al.  Resisting Influence: How the Strength of Predispositions to Resist Control Can Change Strategies for Optimal Opinion Control in the Voter Model , 2018, Front. Robot. AI.

[15]  Mark Newman,et al.  Networks: An Introduction , 2010 .

[16]  Xiaokui Xiao,et al.  Influence maximization: near-optimal time complexity meets practical efficiency , 2014, SIGMOD Conference.

[17]  Christoph Niemann,et al.  Optimal Opinion Control: The Campaign Problem , 2015, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation.

[18]  Srinivas Shakkottai,et al.  Influence maximization in social networks: An ising-model-based approach , 2010, 2010 48th Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing (Allerton).

[19]  Naoki Masuda,et al.  Opinion control in complex networks , 2014, ArXiv.

[20]  M. Opper,et al.  An Idiosyncratic Journey Beyond Mean Field Theory , 2001 .

[21]  Santiago L. Rovere,et al.  Ising-like agent-based technology diffusion model: adoption patterns vs. seeding strategies , 2010, ArXiv.

[22]  Mehmet E. Yildiz,et al.  Binary Opinion Dynamics with Stubborn Agents , 2013, TEAC.

[23]  Matthew Richardson,et al.  Mining knowledge-sharing sites for viral marketing , 2002, KDD.

[24]  Neal Madras,et al.  The noisy voter model , 1995 .

[25]  Daniel D. Lee,et al.  Maximizing Influence in an Ising Network: A Mean-Field Optimal Solution , 2016, NIPS.

[26]  S. Fortunato,et al.  Statistical physics of social dynamics , 2007, 0710.3256.

[27]  Marco Alberto Javarone,et al.  Modeling Radicalization Phenomena in Heterogeneous Populations , 2015, PloS one.

[28]  M. Mobilia,et al.  Voting and catalytic processes with inhomogeneities. , 2004, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[29]  P. Clifford,et al.  A model for spatial conflict , 1973 .

[30]  Dustin Arendt,et al.  Opinions, influence, and zealotry: a computational study on stubbornness , 2015, Computational and Mathematical Organization Theory.

[31]  Shlomo Havlin,et al.  How does public opinion become extreme? , 2014, Scientific Reports.

[32]  Shishir Bharathi,et al.  Competitive Influence Maximization in Social Networks , 2007, WINE.

[33]  Adrian Carro,et al.  The noisy voter model on complex networks , 2016, Scientific Reports.

[34]  Raúl Toral,et al.  Markets, Herding and Response to External Information , 2015, PloS one.

[35]  Allan Borodin,et al.  Threshold Models for Competitive Influence in Social Networks , 2010, WINE.

[36]  Wei Chen,et al.  Scalable influence maximization for independent cascade model in large-scale social networks , 2012, Data Mining and Knowledge Discovery.

[37]  Alan Kirman,et al.  Ants, Rationality, and Recruitment , 1993 .

[38]  Raul Toral,et al.  Zealots in the mean-field noisy voter model. , 2017, Physical review. E.

[39]  Yifei Yuan,et al.  Scalable Influence Maximization in Social Networks under the Linear Threshold Model , 2010, 2010 IEEE International Conference on Data Mining.