NUMEROUS MARKETS ARE characterized by informational differences between buyers and sellers. In financial markets, informational asymmetries are particularly pronounced. Borrowers typically know their collateral, industriousness, and moral rectitude better than do lenders; entrepreneurs possess "inside" information about their own projects for which they seek financing. Lenders would benefit from knowing the true characteristics of borrowers. But moral hazard hampers the direct transfer of information between market participants. Borrowers cannot be expected to be entirely straightforward about their characteristics, nor entrepreneurs about their projects, since there may be substantial rewards for exaggerating positive qualities. And verification of true characteristics by outside parties may be costly or impossible. Without information transfer, markets may perform poorly. Consider the financing of projects whose quality is highly variable. While entrepreneurs know the quality of their own projects, lenders cannot distinguish among them. Market value, therefore, must reflect average project quality. If the market were to place an average value greater than average cost on projects, the potential supply of low quality projects may be very large, since entrepreneurs could foist these upon an uninformed market (retaining little or no equity) and make a sure profit. But this argues that the average quality is likely to be low, with the consequence that even projects which are known (by the entrepreneur) to merit financing cannot be undertaken because of the high cost of capital resulting from low average project quality. Thus, where substantial information asymmetries exist and where the supply of poor projects is large relative to the supply of good projects, venture capital markets may fail to exist. For projects of good quality to be financed, information transfer must occur. We have argued that moral hazard prevents direct information transfer. Nonetheless, information on project quality may be transferred if the actions of entrepreneurs ("which speak louder than words") can be observed. One such action, observable because of disclosure rules, is the willingness of the person(s) with inside information to invest in the project or firm. This willingness to invest may serve as a signal to the lending market of the true quality of the project; lenders will place a value
[1]
George A. Akerlof.
The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism
,
1970
.
[2]
Merton H. Miller.
The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment
,
1958
.
[3]
Joseph E. Stiglitz,et al.
Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information
,
1976
.
[4]
S. Ross.
Some Notes on Financial Incentive-Signalling Models, Activity Choice and Risk Preferences
,
1978
.
[5]
M. Spence.
Competitive and optimal responses to signals: An analysis of efficiency and distribution
,
1974
.
[6]
George J. Benston,et al.
A Transactions Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial Intermediation
,
1976
.
[7]
Information and economic analysis
,
1975
.
[8]
M. C. Jensen,et al.
Harvard Business School; SSRN; National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER); European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI); Harvard University - Accounting & Control Unit
,
1976
.
[9]
M. Spence.
Job Market Signaling
,
1973
.