Does a reduction in the price of rhino horn prevent poaching

Abstract Rhino poaching around the world has increased inordinately, to the extent that concerns exist over the possible survival of the species. An open access rhino poaching model is developed for South African rhino. The model is a hybrid dynamical model, as both a system dynamics model as well as a Bayesian network model are developed. The system dynamics model is used to estimate the unknown parameter values (through optimisation) and also to determine the intervals for the parameters. These intervals are then used in the Bayesian Belief Network model to assess uncertainty. Hybrid approaches improve the ability to validate models compared with conventional modelling. The resultant model indicates that reducing the price of rhino horn would not be effective at curbing poaching, unless poacher costs are also increased. However, increasing poacher costs is not a realistic policy option since these costs are largely beyond the control of decision-makers. The insensitivity of price to poaching effort has implications for methods proposed to reduce the value of rhinos, such as introducing synthetic rhino horn and the de-horning of rhinos.

[1]  Takuro Uehara Ecological threshold and ecological economic threshold: Implications from an ecological economic model with adaptation , 2013 .

[2]  J. Cain Planning improvements in natural resource management. Guidelines for using Bayesian networks to support the planning and management of development programmes in the water sector and beyond , 2001 .

[3]  Yaman Barlas,et al.  Formal aspects of model validity and validation in system dynamics , 1996 .

[4]  Atte Moilanen,et al.  Identification of policies for a sustainable legal trade in rhinoceros horn based on population projection and socioeconomic models , 2014, Conservation biology : the journal of the Society for Conservation Biology.

[5]  E. J. Milner-Gulland,et al.  When does spatial structure matter in models of wildlife harvesting , 2007 .

[6]  J. Blignaut,et al.  Debunking the myth that a legal trade will solve the rhino horn crisis: A system dynamics model for market demand , 2015 .

[7]  Yaman Barlas,et al.  A dynamic model of salinization on irrigated lands , 2001 .

[8]  C. Bellard,et al.  Overcoming extinction: understanding processes of recovery of the Tibetan antelope , 2015 .

[9]  Robert L. Eberlein,et al.  Understanding models with Vensim , 1992 .

[10]  Erwin H. Bulte,et al.  Open access harvesting of wildlife: the poaching pit and conservation of endangered species , 2003 .

[11]  N. Bunnefeld,et al.  Management strategy evaluation: a powerful tool for conservation? , 2011, Trends in ecology & evolution.

[12]  Geoff Coyle,et al.  The validation of commercial system dynamics models , 2000 .

[13]  Douglas J. Crookes,et al.  Improved decision-making on irrigation farming in arid zones using a system dynamics model , 2013 .

[14]  J. Brander,et al.  The Simple Economics of Easter Island: A Ricardo-Malthus Model of Renewable Resource Use , 1998 .

[15]  E. Milner‐Gulland How many to dehorn? A model for decision‐making by rhino managers , 1999 .

[16]  Kevin B. Korb,et al.  Bayesian Artificial Intelligence , 2004, Computer science and data analysis series.

[17]  A. Charles,et al.  Fisheries Regulation and the Incentives to Overfish , 1992 .

[18]  J. Blignaut,et al.  Predator-prey analysis using system dynamics: an application to the steel industry , 2016 .

[19]  A. Collins,et al.  Culture, conservation and crime: regulating ivory markets for antiques and crafts , 2017 .

[20]  E. J. Milner-Gulland,et al.  Unintended Feedbacks: Challenges and Opportunities for Improving Conservation Effectiveness , 2016 .

[21]  E. Milner‐Gulland,et al.  A model of incentives for the illegal exploitation of black rhinos and elephants : poaching pays in Luangwa Valley, Zambia , 1992 .

[22]  John W. Hearne,et al.  Using models in the management of Black Rhino populations , 2002 .

[23]  J. Blignaut,et al.  A categorisation and evaluation of rhino management policies , 2016 .

[24]  Trond Bjorndal,et al.  The dynamics of an open access fishery , 1987, Fisheries Economics.

[25]  E. Milner‐Gulland,et al.  Evaluating the Design of Behavior Change Interventions: A Case Study of Rhino Horn in Vietnam , 2018 .

[26]  J. Opsomer,et al.  An Open-Access Analysis of the Northern Anchovy Fishery , 1994 .

[27]  Andrew R. Teel,et al.  Hybrid Dynamical Systems with Finite Memory , 2016 .

[28]  D. Crookes Modelling the ecological-economic impacts of restoring natural capital, with a special focus on water and agriculture, at eight sites in South Africa , 2012 .

[29]  E. Milner‐Gulland,et al.  Endangering the endangered: The effects of perceived rarity on species exploitation , 2008 .

[30]  Trading on extinction: An open-access deterrence model for the South African abalone fishery , 2016 .

[31]  Common Property Resources and the Dynamics of Overexploitation: The Case of the North Pacific Fur Seal , 2018, Marine Resource Economics.

[32]  A. Ford Modeling the Environment: An Introduction To System Dynamics Modeling Of Environmental Systems , 1999 .

[33]  E. Milner‐Gulland An econometric analysis of consumer demand for ivory and rhino horn , 1993 .