Software Exclusivity and the Scope of Indirect Network Effects in the U.S. Home Video Game Market

This paper investigates the scope of indirect network effects in the home video game industry. We argue that the increasing prevalence of non-exclusive software gives rise to indirect network effects that exist between users of competing and incompatible hardware platforms. This is because software non-exclusivity, like hardware compatibility, allows a software firm to sell to a market broader than a single platform's installed base. We look for evidence of market-wide network effects by estimating a model of hardware demand and software supply. Our software supply equation allows the supply of games for a particular platform to depend not only on the installed base of that platform, but also on the installed base of competing platforms. Our results indicate the presence of both a platform-specific network effect and--in recent years--a cross-platform (or generation-wide) network effect. Our finding that the scope of indirect network effects in this industry has widened suggests one reason that this market, which is often cited as a canonical example of one with strong indirect network effects, is no longer dominated by a single platform.

[1]  Neil Gandal,et al.  NETWORK EFFECTS, SOFTWARE PROVISION, AND STANDARDIZATION* , 1992 .

[2]  Marc Rysman,et al.  Competition between Networks: A Study of the Market for Yellow Pages , 2002 .

[3]  Harikesh S. Nair,et al.  Empirical Analysis of Indirect Network Effects in the Market for Personal Digital Assistants , 2004 .

[4]  Wei-Min Hu,et al.  An Empirical Analysis of Indirect Network Effects in the Home Video Game Market , 2006 .

[5]  Harikesh S. Nair,et al.  Empirical Analysis of Indirect Network Effects in the Market for Personal Digital Assistants , 2004 .

[6]  Neil Gandal,et al.  The Dynamics of Technological Adoption in Hardware/Software Systems , 1997 .

[7]  Dale A. Stirling,et al.  Information rules , 2003, SGMD.

[8]  C. Shapiro,et al.  Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility , 1985 .

[9]  Christiaan Hogendorn,et al.  Platform Competition with ‘Must-Have’ Components , 2009 .

[10]  M. Armstrong Competition in Two-Sided Markets ¤ , 2005 .

[11]  Steven T. Berry Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation , 1994 .

[12]  Sangin Park Quantitative Analysis of Network Externalities in Competing Technologies: The VCR Case , 2004, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[13]  Matthew T. Clements,et al.  Indirect Network Effects and the Product Cycle: Video Games in the U.S., 1994-2002 , 2004 .

[14]  Ulrich Kaiser,et al.  Price structure in two-sided markets: Evidence from the magazine industry , 2006 .

[15]  Neil Gandal,et al.  Competing Compatibility Standards and Network Externalities in the PC Software Market , 1995 .

[16]  Matthew T. Clements,et al.  Direct and Indirect Network Effects: Are They Equivalent? , 2004 .

[17]  J. Rochet,et al.  Platform competition in two sided markets , 2003 .

[18]  H. Ohashi The Role of Network Effects in the US VCR Market, 1978-1986 , 2003 .

[19]  Marius Schwartz,et al.  Compatibility Incentives of a Large Network Facing Multiple Rivals , 2006 .

[20]  Siva Viswanathan,et al.  Exclusive Licensing in Complementary Network Industries , 2007 .

[21]  Venkatesh Shankar,et al.  Network Effects and Competition: An Empirical Analysis of the Home Video Game Industry , 2002 .

[22]  Matthew T. Clements,et al.  Indirect Network Effects and the Product Cycle: Video Games in the U.S., 1994-2002 , 2004 .

[23]  Steven T. Berry,et al.  Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium , 1995 .

[24]  Neil Gandal,et al.  Adoptions and Orphans in the Early Microcomputer Market , 2003 .