When are Contrarian Profits Due to Stock Market Overreaction?

The profitability of contrarian investment strategies need not be the result of stock market overreaction. Even if returns on individual securities are temporally independent, portfolio strategies that attempt to exploit return reversals may still earn positive expected profits. This is due to the effects of cross-autocovariances from which contrarian strategies inadvertently benefit. We provide an informal taxonomy of return-generating processes that yield positive [and negative] expected profits under a particular contrarian portfolio strategy, and use this taxonomy to reconcile the empirical findings of weak negative autocorrelation for returns on individual stocks with the strong positive autocorrelation of portfolio returns. We present empirical evidence against overreaction as the primary source of contrarian profits, and show the presence of important lead-lag relations across securities.

[1]  M. Nimalendran,et al.  Components of short-horizon individual security returns , 1991 .

[2]  Narasimhan Jegadeesh,et al.  Evidence of Predictable Behavior of Security Returns , 1990 .

[3]  Paul Zarowin,et al.  Size, Seasonality, and Stock Market Overreaction , 1990, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[4]  A. Lo,et al.  An Econometric Analysis of Nonsynchronous Trading , 1989 .

[5]  L. Summers,et al.  Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation , 1989 .

[6]  Richard Startz,et al.  Mean Reversion in Stock Prices? a Reappraisal of the Empirical Evidence , 1988 .

[7]  E. Fama,et al.  Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock Prices , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[8]  J. Poterba,et al.  Mean Reversion in Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications , 1987 .

[9]  R. Thaler,et al.  Further Evidence On Investor Overreaction and Stock Market Seasonality , 1987 .

[10]  P. Phillips Time series regression with a unit root , 1987 .

[11]  A. Lo,et al.  Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test , 1987 .

[12]  L. Summers Does the Stock Market Rationally Reflect Fundamental Values , 1986 .

[13]  W. Newey,et al.  A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelationconsistent Covariance Matrix , 1986 .

[14]  Kalman J. Cohen,et al.  The Microstructure of Securities Markets , 1986 .

[15]  Michael D. Atchison,et al.  NONSYNCHRONOUS SECURITY TRADING AND MARKET INDEX AUTOCORRELATION , 1985 .

[16]  R. Thaler,et al.  Does the Stock Market Overreact , 1985 .

[17]  M. Statman,et al.  The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long , 1985 .

[18]  H. White Asymptotic theory for econometricians , 1985 .

[19]  R. Roll,et al.  A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask Spread in an Efficient Market , 2008 .

[20]  Michael A. Goldberg,et al.  The changing role of the individual investor , 1979 .

[21]  R. Lucas ASSET PRICES IN AN EXCHANGE ECONOMY , 1978 .

[22]  Myron S. Scholes,et al.  Estimating betas from nonsynchronous data , 1977 .

[23]  Stephen F. LeRoy,et al.  Risk Aversion and the Martingale Property of Stock Prices , 1973 .

[24]  E. Fama EFFICIENT CAPITAL MARKETS: A REVIEW OF THEORY AND EMPIRICAL WORK* , 1970 .

[25]  Lawrence Fisher,et al.  Some New Stock-Market Indexes , 1966 .

[26]  C. Granger,et al.  The Random Character of Stock Market Prices. , 1965 .

[27]  E. Fama The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices , 1965 .

[28]  B. Arnold,et al.  MOORE, . Some Characteristics of Changes in Common Stock Prices Cootner, ed. The Random Character of Stock Market Prices, pp. . Cambridge: The . , 1964 .

[29]  L. Bachelier,et al.  Theory of Speculation , 1964 .