A bottom-up institutional approach to cooperative governance of risky commons

Climate change cooperation has been limited by the lack of sanctioning mechanisms to deal with those who fail to abide by agreements. Research now shows that a bottom-up process, in which parties create local institutions that punish free-riders, promotes widespread cooperation as opposed to the traditional top-down approach that builds global institutions. Avoiding the effects of climate change may be framed as a public goods dilemma1, in which the risk of future losses is non-negligible2,3,4,5,6,7, while realizing that the public good may be far in the future3,7,8,9. The limited success of existing attempts to reach global cooperation has been also associated with a lack of sanctioning institutions and mechanisms to deal with those who do not contribute to the welfare of the planet or fail to abide by agreements1,3,10,11,12,13. Here we investigate the emergence and impact of different types of sanctioning to deter non-cooperative behaviour in climate agreements. We show that a bottom-up approach, in which parties create local institutions that punish free-riders, promotes the emergence of widespread cooperation, mostly when risk perception is low, as it is at present3,7. On the contrary, global institutions provide, at best, marginal improvements regarding overall cooperation. Our results clearly suggest that a polycentric approach involving multiple institutions is more effective than that associated with a single, global one, indicating that such a bottom-up, self-organization approach, set up at a local scale, provides a better ground on which to attempt a solution for such a complex and global dilemma.

[1]  L. Imhof,et al.  Stochasticity and evolutionary stability. , 2006, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[2]  M. Nowak,et al.  Stochastic dynamics of invasion and fixation. , 2006, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[3]  W. Ebeling Stochastic Processes in Physics and Chemistry , 1995 .

[4]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics , 1998 .

[5]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  Mutation-selection equilibrium in games with multiple strategies. , 2008, Journal of theoretical biology.

[6]  Heike Schroeder,et al.  Institutions and Environmental Change: Principal Findings, Applications, and Research Frontiers , 2008 .

[7]  Manfred Milinski,et al.  The Calculus of Selfishness , 2011 .

[8]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[9]  Long Wang,et al.  Universality of weak selection. , 2010, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[10]  Danièle Revel,et al.  Cities and climate change : an urgent agenda , 2011 .

[11]  Bengt Kriström,et al.  Uncertainty and Climate Change , 2002 .

[12]  C. Hauert,et al.  Coevolutionary dynamics: from finite to infinite populations. , 2004, Physical review letters.

[13]  Armin W. Schulz Signals: evolution, learning, and information , 2012 .

[14]  Jonathan Anomaly,et al.  Why Cooperate? The Incentive to Supply Global Public Goods , 2009 .

[15]  Jochem Marotzke,et al.  The collective-risk social dilemma and the prevention of simulated dangerous climate change , 2008, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[16]  R. Hinde,et al.  The Possibility of Cooperation@@@Cooperation: The Basis of Sociability.@@@Cooperation and Prosocial Behavior.@@@Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. , 1990 .

[17]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Reacting differently to adverse ties promotes cooperation in social networks. , 2009, Physical review letters.

[18]  M. Milinski,et al.  Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’ , 2002, Nature.

[19]  Chaitanya S. Gokhale,et al.  Evolutionary games in the multiverse , 2010, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[20]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Risk of collective failure provides an escape from the tragedy of the commons , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[21]  K. Carman,et al.  Social Influences and the Private Provision of Public Goods: Evidence from Charitable Contributions in the Workplace , 2003 .

[22]  M. Nowak Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life , 2006 .

[23]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Social learning promotes institutions for governing the commons , 2010, Nature.

[24]  S. Barrett Avoiding disastrous climate change is possible but not inevitable , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[25]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Imitation Processes with Small Mutations , 2004, J. Econ. Theory.

[26]  P. Richerson,et al.  The evolution of indirect reciprocity , 1989 .

[27]  Francisco C. Santos,et al.  Stern-Judging: A Simple, Successful Norm Which Promotes Cooperation under Indirect Reciprocity , 2006, PLoS Comput. Biol..

[28]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Exploration dynamics in evolutionary games , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[29]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Emergence of responsible sanctions without second order free riders, antisocial punishment or spite , 2012, Scientific Reports.

[30]  H. Roche,et al.  Why Copy Others? Insights from the Social Learning Strategies Tournament , 2010 .

[31]  H. Schroeder,et al.  Equity and State Representations in Climate Negotiations , 2012 .

[32]  M. McGinty International Environmental Agreements as Evolutionary Games , 2010 .

[33]  Scott Barrett,et al.  Climate negotiations under scientific uncertainty , 2012, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[34]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Stochastic payoff evaluation increases the temperature of selection. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[35]  Ivana Chlapcová Environment and Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental Treaty-making , 2006 .

[36]  Jochem Marotzke,et al.  Stabilizing the earth's climate is not a losing game: supporting evidence from public goods experiments. , 2006, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[37]  Torsten Röhl,et al.  Cooperative interaction of rich and poor can be catalyzed by intermediate climate targets , 2011 .

[38]  Michael Tomasello,et al.  Primate Cognition , 2010, Top. Cogn. Sci..

[39]  Benjamin J. Richardson Environment and Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental Treaty-making, by S. Barrett , 2005 .

[40]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Emergence of fairness in repeated group interactions. , 2012, Physical review letters.

[41]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Evolutionary cycles of cooperation and defection. , 2005, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[42]  Nikos Nikiforakis,et al.  Punishment and Counter-punishment in Public Good Games: Can We Still Govern Ourselves? , 2005 .

[43]  C. Gilbert Policy & Research Working Paper , 1996 .

[44]  Francisco C. Santos,et al.  Co-evolution of pre-play signaling and cooperation , 2011, ECAL.

[45]  Eörs Szathmáry,et al.  The Major Transitions in Evolution , 1997 .

[46]  Maja Schlüter,et al.  The survival of the conformist: social pressure and renewable resource management , 2010 .

[47]  J. Peinke,et al.  Principal axes for stochastic dynamics. , 2011, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[48]  Alessandro Tavoni,et al.  Inequality, communication, and the avoidance of disastrous climate change in a public goods game , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[49]  M. Utku Ünver,et al.  A nonsimultaneous, extended, altruistic-donor chain. , 2009, The New England journal of medicine.

[50]  G. Brady Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action , 1993 .

[51]  C. Hauert,et al.  Synergy and discounting of cooperation in social dilemmas. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[52]  Maja Schlüter,et al.  The Survival of the Conformist: Social Pressure and Renewable Resource Management , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[53]  Torsten Röhl,et al.  An economic experiment reveals that humans prefer pool punishment to maintain the commons , 2012, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[54]  Simon A. Levin,et al.  Learning to live in a global commons: socioeconomic challenges for a sustainable environment , 2006, Ecological Research.

[55]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Evolutionary Dynamics of Strategic Behavior in a Collective-Risk Dilemma , 2012, PLoS Comput. Biol..

[56]  K. Arrow,et al.  Looming Global-Scale Failures and Missing Institutions , 2009, Science.

[57]  Martin A Nowak,et al.  Multiple strategies in structured populations , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[58]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics of collective action in N-person stag hunt dilemmas , 2009, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[59]  George Sugihara,et al.  Complex systems: Ecology for bankers , 2008, Nature.

[60]  Amy R. Poteete,et al.  Working Together: Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice , 2010 .

[61]  P. Richerson,et al.  Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups , 1992 .

[62]  Rajiv Sethi,et al.  The Evolution of Social Norms in Common Property Resource Use , 1996 .

[63]  Nicholas A. Christakis,et al.  Cooperative behavior cascades in human social networks , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[64]  Montserrat Viladrich-Grau,et al.  On the sustainability of common property resources , 2007 .

[65]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  The different limits of weak selection and the evolutionary dynamics of finite populations. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[66]  C. Hauert,et al.  Via Freedom to Coercion: The Emergence of Costly Punishment , 2007, Science.

[67]  M. Nowak Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation , 2006, Science.