Communication in context: Interpreting promises in an experiment on competition and trust

Significance Does competition increase deception? Competition is likely to induce inflated promises, but are these promises believed, and are they followed through? We argue that the question requires care in the definition of deception. We report on an experiment where competition does indeed inflate promises, but the promises are neither believed literally nor discarded. Bigger promises are interpreted by both sides as signals of equitable intentions, without being meant or read literally. Behavior does not follow the letter of the promise, but we argue that the deviation is not perceived as deception—the language code has changed. Analyses of competition, deception, and trust need to take into account the shared understanding of the message itself. How much do people lie, and how much do people trust communication when lying is possible? An important step toward answering these questions is understanding how communication is interpreted. This paper establishes in a canonical experiment that competition can alter the shared communication code: the commonly understood meaning of messages. We study a sender–receiver game in which the sender dictates how to share $10 with the receiver, if the receiver participates. The receiver has an outside option and decides whether to participate after receiving a nonbinding offer from the sender. Competition for play between senders leads to higher offers but has no effect on actual transfers, expected transfers, or receivers’ willingness to play. The higher offers signal that sharing will be equitable without the expectation that they should be followed literally: Under competition “6 is the new 5.”

[1]  Roy Sorensen,et al.  BALD-FACED LIES! LYING WITHOUT THE INTENT TO DECEIVE , 2007 .

[2]  Natalia Karelaia,et al.  Does competition foster trust? The role of tournament incentives , 2012 .

[3]  Christoph Vanberg,et al.  WHY DO PEOPLE KEEP THEIR PROMISES? AN EXPERIMENTAL TEST OF TWO EXPLANATIONS , 2008 .

[4]  Joyce E. Berg,et al.  Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History , 1995 .

[5]  C. Bartneck,et al.  Comparing the Similarity of Responses Received from Studies in Amazon’s Mechanical Turk to Studies Conducted Online and with Direct Recruitment , 2015, PloS one.

[6]  Jean-Robert Tyran,et al.  Competition Fosters Trust , 2006, Games Econ. Behav..

[7]  L. Putterman,et al.  Lavish returns on cheap talk: Two-way communication in trust games , 2011 .

[8]  J. Abeler,et al.  Preferences for Truth-Telling , 2016, Econometrica.

[9]  Alberto Abadie Bootstrap Tests for Distributional Treatment Effects in Instrumental Variable Models , 2002 .

[10]  Tore Ellingsen,et al.  Testing guilt aversion , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[11]  J. Goeree,et al.  Communication and Competition , 2012 .

[12]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  Author's Personal Copy Games and Economic Behavior the Framing of Games and the Psychology of Play , 2022 .

[13]  David G. Rand,et al.  The online laboratory: conducting experiments in a real labor market , 2010, ArXiv.

[14]  T. Carson,et al.  The Definition of Lying , 2006 .

[15]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  Promises and Partnership , 2006 .

[16]  Navin Kartik,et al.  Strategic Communication with Lying Costs , 2009 .

[17]  U. Fischbacher,et al.  Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Fairness, Errors and the Power of Competition , 2022 .

[18]  Navin Kartik,et al.  Would I lie to you? On social preferences and lying aversion , 2009 .

[19]  Andrew Schotter,et al.  Fairness and survival in ultimatum and dictatorship games , 1996 .

[20]  Pierpaolo Battigalli,et al.  Deception: The role of guilt , 2013 .

[21]  J. Morgan,et al.  Cheap Talk , 2005 .

[22]  Jeffrey S. Banks,et al.  A model of electoral competition with incomplete information , 1990 .

[23]  Pierpaolo Battigalli,et al.  Guilt in Games , 2007 .

[24]  J. Sobel,et al.  STRATEGIC INFORMATION TRANSMISSION , 1982 .

[25]  Uri Gneezy,et al.  Deception: The Role of Consequences , 2005 .

[26]  Sebastian Kube,et al.  Elections and Deceptions: An Experimental Study on the Behavioral Effects of Democracy , 2013 .

[27]  Carmen Tanner,et al.  Preferences for Truthfulness: Heterogeneity Among and Within Individuals , 2012 .

[28]  Florian Ederer,et al.  Promises and Expectations , 2017, Games Econ. Behav..

[29]  Jörgen W. Weibull,et al.  KS Language , meaning and games : a model of communication , coordination and evolution , 2007 .

[30]  Joseph Farrell Meaning and Credibility in Cheap-Talk Games , 1993 .

[31]  J. Potters,et al.  Why do promises affect trustworthiness, or do they? , 2016 .

[32]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  Bare promises: An experiment , 2010 .

[33]  Yusuke Narita,et al.  Guilt aversion revisited: An experimental test of a new model , 2014 .

[34]  U. Fischbacher z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments , 1999 .

[35]  J. Tirole,et al.  Incentives and Prosocial Behavior , 2005 .

[36]  David F. Sally `What an Ugly Baby!' , 2002 .

[37]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  Measuring Beliefs in an Experimental Lost Wallet Game , 2000, Games Econ. Behav..