Subject-Specific Performance Information can Worsen the Tragedy of the Commons: Experimental Evidence

The main aim of this article is to investigate the behavioral consequences of the provision of subject-specific information in the group effort levels chosen by players in an experimental CPR game. We examine two basic treatments, one with incomplete information and the other with complete information. In the former, subjects are informed only about their own individual payoffs and the aggregate extraction effort level of the group, and in the latter they are also informed about the individual effort levels and payoffs of each subject. Given this setting, the basic question we attempt to answer is: Will the provision of subject-specific performance information (i.e. individual’s effort levels and payoffs) improve or worsen the tragedy of the commons (i.e. an exploitation effort level greater than the socially optimum level)? In order to motivate our hypotheses and explain our experimental results at the individual level, we make use of the theory of learning in games, which goes beyond standard non-cooperative game theory, allowing us to explore the three basic benchmarks in the commons context: Nash equilibrium, Pareto efficient, and open access outcomes. We use several learning and imitation theoretical models that are based on contrasting assumptions about the level of rationality and the information available to subjects, namely: best response, imitate the average, mix of best response and imitate the average, imitate the best and follow the exemplary learning rules. Finally, in order to econometrically test the hypotheses formulated from the theoretical predictions we use a random-effects model to assess the explanatory power of the different selected behavioral learning and imitation rules.

[1]  Y. Mundlak On the Pooling of Time Series and Cross Section Data , 1978 .

[2]  Hans von Storch,et al.  Taking Serial Correlation into Account in Tests of the Mean. , 1995 .

[3]  Jose Apesteguia,et al.  Does information matter in the commons?: Experimental evidence , 2006 .

[4]  James M. Walker,et al.  Collective Action with Incomplete Commitment: Experimental Evidence , 2000 .

[5]  Elinor Ostrom,et al.  The value-added of laboratory experiments for the study of institutions and common-pool resources , 2006 .

[6]  W. Hamilton,et al.  Selfish and Spiteful Behaviour in an Evolutionary Model , 1970, Nature.

[7]  S. Huck,et al.  Stability of the Cournot Process: Experimental Evidence , 1997 .

[8]  Charles R. Plott,et al.  Decentralized management of common property resources: experiments with a centuries-old institution , 2003 .

[9]  F. Vega-Redondo The evolution of Walrasian behavior , 1997 .

[10]  S. Huck,et al.  Learning in Cournot Oligopoly - An Experiment , 1999 .

[11]  S. Hanna,et al.  Common property economics: a general theory and land use applications: Glenn G. Stevenson. Cambridge University Press, 1991. ISBN 0 521 38441 9 , 1994 .

[12]  Elinor Ostrom,et al.  Collective Choice in the Commons: Experimental Results on Proposed Allocation Rules and Votes , 2000 .

[13]  D. Levine Modeling Altruism and Spitefulness in Experiments , 1998 .

[14]  Nicolaas J. Vriend,et al.  Imitation of successful behaviour in cournot markets , 2003 .

[15]  Juan Camilo Cárdenas,et al.  Real Wealth and Experimental Cooperation: Evidence from Field Experiments , 2002 .

[16]  Karl H. Schlag,et al.  Which One Should I Imitate , 1999 .

[17]  Vasilis Sarafidis,et al.  Testing for Cross-Sectional Dependence in Panel-Data Models , 2006 .

[18]  Elinor Ostrom,et al.  Rent dissipation in a limited-access common-pool resource: Experimental evidence , 1990 .

[19]  Karl H. Schlag Imitation and Social Learning , 2011 .

[20]  E. Ostrom,et al.  Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources , 1994 .

[21]  Ana B. Ania,et al.  The evolutionary stability of perfectly competitive behavior , 2005 .

[22]  E. Ostrom,et al.  Covenants with and without a Sword: Self-Governance Is Possible , 1992, American Political Science Review.

[23]  S. Basov Imitation And Social Learning , 2002 .

[24]  David F. Sally Conversation and Cooperation in Social Dilemmas , 1995 .

[25]  Sophia Rabe-Hesketh,et al.  Generalized latent variable models: multilevel, longitudinal, and structural equation models , 2004 .

[26]  Theo Offerman,et al.  Forthcoming Review of Economic Studies Imitation and Belief Learning in an Oligopoly Experiment , 2002 .

[27]  P. Seabright Managing Local Commons: Theoretical Issues in Incentive Design , 1993 .

[28]  J. Cárdenas,et al.  Local environmental control and institutional crowding-out. , 2000 .

[29]  C. Plott,et al.  Handbook of Experimental Economics Results , 2008 .

[30]  H Scottgordon The economic theory of a common-property resource: The fishery , 1991 .

[31]  P. Dasgupta,et al.  Economic Theory and Exhaustible Resources. , 1980 .

[32]  Juan Camilo Cárdenas,et al.  Real wealth and experimental cooperation: experiments in the field lab , 2003 .

[33]  L. Corrado Generalized Latent Variable Modeling: Multilevel, Longitudinal, and Structural Equation Models , 2005 .

[34]  Edella Schlager,et al.  The role of communication in resolving commons dilemmas: experimental evidence with heterogeneous appropriators , 1994 .

[35]  J. Cárdenas How Do Groups Solve Local Commons Dilemmas? Lessons from Experimental Economics in the Field , 2000 .

[36]  Elinor Ostrom,et al.  Governing the commons , 1990 .

[37]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  The Theory of Learning in Games , 1998 .