Do Liars Believe? Beliefs and Other-Regarding Preferences in the Sender-Receiver Game

We examine subjects’ behavior in sender–receiver games where there are gains from trade and alignment of interests in one of the two states. We elicit subjects’ beliefs, risk and other-regarding preferences. Our design also allows us to examine the behavior of subjects in both roles, to determine whether the behavior in one role is the best response to the subject's own behavior in the other role. The results of the experiment indicate that, when acting as senders, the majority of subjects adopt deceptive strategies by sending favorable message when the true state of the nature is unfavorable. When acting as receivers, the majority of subjects invest conditional upon receiving a favorable message. The investing behavior of receivers cannot be explained by risk preferences or as a best response to subject's own behavior in the sender's role. However, it can be rationalized by accounting for elicited beliefs and other-regarding preferences. Finally, the honest behavior of some senders can be explained by other-regarding preferences. Thus, we that find liars do believe, and that individuals who care about the payoffs of others tend to be honest.

[1]  Roman M. Sheremeta,et al.  Side-Payments and the Costs of Conflict , 2012 .

[2]  Roman M. Sheremeta,et al.  Can groups solve the problem of over-bidding in contests? , 2009, Soc. Choice Welf..

[3]  Uri Gneezy,et al.  Deception: The Role of Consequences , 2005 .

[4]  Ismael Rodriguez-Lara,et al.  Are you a good employee or simply a good guy? Influence Costs and Contract Design , 2013 .

[5]  Navin Kartik,et al.  Would I lie to you? On social preferences and lying aversion , 2009 .

[6]  Steven Gjerstad,et al.  Housing Market Price Tier Movements in an Expansion and Collapse , 2009 .

[7]  Martin Strobel,et al.  Inequality Aversion, Efficiency, and Maximin Preferences in Simple Distribution Experiments , 2002 .

[8]  E. Fehr A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation , 1998 .

[9]  Jordi Brandts,et al.  The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons , 2011 .

[10]  Roman M. Sheremeta,et al.  The Equivalence of Contests , 2009 .

[11]  Geoffrey B. Sprinkle,et al.  Experimental evidence on the evolution of meaning of messages in sender-receiver games , 1998 .

[12]  U. Fischbacher z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments , 1999 .

[13]  Roman M. Sheremeta,et al.  Contest Design: An Experimental Investigation , 2009 .

[14]  Joseph Tao-Yi Wang,et al.  Overcommunication in strategic information transmission games , 2006, Games Econ. Behav..

[15]  R. Zeckhauser,et al.  Trust, Risk and Betrayal , 2003 .

[16]  J. Sonnemans,et al.  Value Orientations, Expectations and Voluntary Contributions in Public Goods. , 1996 .

[17]  Ernst Fehr,et al.  Egalitarianism and Competitiveness , 2009 .

[18]  Alexander K. Koch,et al.  Belief elicitation in experiments: is there a hedging problem? , 2010 .

[19]  V. Smith,et al.  Theory and individual behavior of first-price auctions , 1988 .

[20]  Charles A. Holt,et al.  Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects , 2002 .

[21]  David Porter,et al.  Affecting Policy by Manipulating Prediction Markets: Experimental Evidence , 2013 .

[22]  M. Rabin,et al.  Understanding Social Preference with Simple Tests , 2001 .

[23]  Ryan Oprea,et al.  War of Attrition: Evidence from a Laboratory Experiment on Market Exit , 2013 .

[24]  Robert Forsythe,et al.  Cheap Talk, Fraud and Adverse Selection in Financial Markets: Some Experimental Evidence , 1998 .

[25]  Florin P. Vasvari,et al.  Wealth Transfer Effects of Analysts' Misleading Behavior , 2007 .

[26]  Information Management and Valuation: An Experimental Investigation , 2002 .

[27]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Are Under- and Over-reaction the Same Matter? A Price Inertia based Account , 2010 .

[28]  David Porter,et al.  Reaction to Public Information in Markets: How Much Does Ambiguity Matter? , 2013 .

[29]  Navin Kartik,et al.  Credulity, Lies, and Costly Talk , 2007, J. Econ. Theory.

[30]  Marc Vorsatz,et al.  An experimental study of truth-telling in a sender-receiver game , 2007, Games Econ. Behav..

[31]  Matthias Sutter,et al.  Distributional preferences and competitive behavior , 2012, Journal of economic behavior & organization.

[32]  John Dickhaut,et al.  Does information transparency decrease coordination failure? , 2010, Games Econ. Behav..

[33]  J. Sobel,et al.  STRATEGIC INFORMATION TRANSMISSION , 1982 .

[34]  Roni Michaely,et al.  Conflict of interest and the credibility of underwriter analyst recommendations , 1999 .

[35]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  Promises and Partnership , 2006 .

[36]  D. Porter,et al.  Radio Spectrum and the Disruptive Clarity of Ronald Coase , 2010, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[37]  I. Lunde [Conflict of interest and credibility]. , 2011, Ugeskrift for laeger.

[38]  Robin Hanson,et al.  Can Manipulators Mislead Prediction Market Observers , 2008 .

[39]  Kuldeep Shastri,et al.  Underwriter Analyst Recommendations: Conflict of Interest or Rush to Judgement , 1997 .

[40]  S. Rassenti,et al.  Real Effort, Real Leisure and Real-time Supervision: Incentives and Peer Pressure in Virtual Organizations , 2011 .

[41]  Glenn W. Harrison,et al.  Risk Attitudes in First-Price Auction Experiments: A Bayesian Analysis , 1990 .

[42]  David M. Grether,et al.  Intimidation or Impatience? Jump Bidding in On-line Ascending Automobile Auctions , 2011 .

[43]  Peter Ockenfels,et al.  Measuring Strategic Uncertainty in Coordination Games , 2004, SSRN Electronic Journal.