Are Efficiency and Equity in School Finance Substitutes or Complements

This paper analyzes cases made for local and centralized school finance and policies such as vouchers, categorical aid, and equalization aid. An ideal system of school finance would achieve efficiency and equity by ensuring every person invests in the amount of schooling that is socially optimal for him. The author evaluates the empirical evidence for, and the merit and importance of, arguments for each policy. She concludes that the theoretical arguments for centralized finance not only exaggerate the efficiency-equity tradeoff but actually make better arguments for a system combining local school finance with categorical aid and means-tested vouchers.

[1]  M. Boldrin Public Education and Capital Accumulation , 2005 .

[2]  Dennis Epple,et al.  Ends against the middle: Determining public service provision when there are private alternatives , 1996 .

[3]  J. Poterba Demographic Structure and the Political Economy of Public Education , 1996 .

[4]  T. Nechyba Public School Finance in a General Equilibrium Tiebout World: Equalization Programs, Peer Effects and Private School Vouchers , 1996 .

[5]  S. Peltzman Political Economy of Public Education: Non-College-Bound Students , 1996, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[6]  R. Bénabou Equity and Efficiency in Human Capital Investment: The Local Connection , 1996 .

[7]  Richard Rogerson,et al.  Income Distribution, Communities, and the Quality of Public Education , 1996 .

[8]  V. Martinez The consequences of school choice : who leaves and who stays in the inner city , 1995 .

[9]  C. Hoxby Is There an Equity-Efficiency Trade-Off in School Finance? Tiebout and a Theory of the Local Public Goods Producer , 1995 .

[10]  Jon Sonstelie,et al.  DID SERRANO CAUSE A DECLINE IN SCHOOL SPENDING? , 1995, National Tax Journal.

[11]  Lawrence J. White,et al.  The Analytics of the Pricing of Higher Education and Other Services in Which the Customers Are Inputs , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  L. Kenny,et al.  The decline in the number of school districts in the U.S.: 1950–1980 , 1994 .

[13]  D. Epple,et al.  Existence of voting and housing equilibrium in a system of communities with property taxes , 1993 .

[14]  W. Shughart,et al.  Private school enrollment and public school performance , 1993 .

[15]  S. Peltzman The Political Economy of the Decline of American Public Education , 1993, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[16]  G. Bittlingmayer The Stock Market and Early Antitrust Enforcement , 1993, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[17]  R. Zeckhauser,et al.  Demographic Characteristics and the Public Bundle , 1993, Public finance = Finances publiques.

[18]  C. Manski Educational choice (vouchers) and social mobility , 1992 .

[19]  Thomas A. Downes EVALUATING THE IMPACT OF SCHOOL FINANCE REFORM ON THE PROVISION OF PUBLIC EDUCATION: THE CALIFORNIA CASE , 1992, National Tax Journal.

[20]  W. Evans,et al.  Measuring Peer Group Effects: A Study of Teenage Behavior , 1992, Journal of Political Economy.

[21]  M. Borland,et al.  Student academic achievement and the degree of market concentration in education , 1992 .

[22]  R. Bénabou Workings of a City: Location, Education, and Production , 1991 .

[23]  Lawrence F. Katz,et al.  The Company You Keep: The Effects of Family and Neighborhood on Disadvantaged Youths , 1991 .

[24]  Charles A.M. de Bartolome,et al.  Equilibrium and Inefficiency in a Community Model With Peer Group Effects , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[25]  W. Fischel DID "SERRANO" CAUSE PROPOSITION 13? , 1989, National Tax Journal.

[26]  F. Boschee Public and Private High Schools. By James S. Coleman and Thomas Hoffer. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1987 , 1987 .

[27]  J. Brueckner Property value maximization and public sector efficiency , 1983 .

[28]  Kenneth T. Rosen The Impact of Proposition 13 on House Prices in Northern California: A Test of the Interjurisdictional Capitalization Hypothesis , 1982, Journal of Political Economy.

[29]  D. Epple,et al.  The Implications of Competition Among Jurisdictions: Does Tiebout Need Politics? , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[30]  R. Eberts,et al.  Jurisdictional homogeneity and the Tiebout hypothesis , 1981 .

[31]  J. Brueckner Property values, local public expenditure and economic efficiency , 1979 .

[32]  Thomas Romer,et al.  Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo , 1978 .

[33]  W. Niskanen Bureaucrats and Politicians , 1975, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[34]  Joseph E. Stiglitz,et al.  The demand for education in public and private school systems , 1974 .

[35]  Charles M. Tiebout A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures , 1956, Journal of Political Economy.

[36]  Roland Bénabou,et al.  Heterogeneity, Stratification, and Growth: Macroeconomic Implications of Community Structure and School Finance , 1996 .

[37]  James E. Rosenbaum,et al.  Changing the Geography of Opportunity by Expanding Residential Choice: Lessons from the Gautreaux Program , 1995 .

[38]  E. Hanushek,et al.  Understanding the 20th Century Explosion in U.S. School Costs , 1994 .

[39]  Richard Rogrson PUBLIC EDUCATION AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION: A QUANTITATIVE EVALUATION OF EDUCATION FINANCE REFORM , 1994 .

[40]  D. Boaz Liberating Schools: Education in the Inner City. , 1991 .

[41]  Daniel L. Rubinfeld,et al.  The economics of the local public sector , 1987 .

[42]  J. C. Dyer,et al.  Capitalization of Intrajurisdictional Differences in Local Tax Prices: Comment , 1979 .

[43]  Bruce W. Hamilton Capitalization of Intrajurisdictional Differences in Local Tax Prices , 1976 .

[44]  G. Becker,et al.  Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, Third Edition , 1993 .