The Case Against Conservative Macroeconomics: An Inaugural Lecture

Keynesian economics has now reached middle age. With these advancing years the claims of her traditional rival, the quantity theory, have shown their endurance, while a young offspring of the old classical theory, called the New Classical Economics, threatens to take the centre of attention from both of the older theories. This lecture is a defence of Keynesian economics. It proceeds by the admittedly unchivalrous method of pointing out the faults of the two rivals. The issue at hand is what it has always been between Keynesian and conservative macroeconomics, whether the government is able or unable to control real income by macroeconomic interventions. To organize our thoughts it is convenient to choose one exemplar of conservative macroeconomics. For that purpose I have chosen Sargent's model of the economy (Sargent, 1973).1 I do wish to emphasize that the Sargent model is chosen because it is a typical representative of the New Classical Economics. Therefore the remarks here concerning the Sargent model in particular apply with equal force to the New Classical Economics in general. The Sargent model has three equations. The first is an IS curve. Keynesian economists and conservative economists agree, it appears, on the IS curve, at least to a first degree of approximation. The second equation is an LM curve. New Classical economists allow this LM curve to have a non-zero interest elasticity; the old-style conservative economists, who espouse the quantity theory, question the empirical significance of such an interest elasticity. With a significant income elasticity and a zero interest elasticity of the demand for money, fiscal policy can have no effect on money income regardless of the degree of slack in the economy. If not only the interest elasticity, but also the income elasticity, of the demand for money is low, however, fiscal policy can be effective in changing real income. The fault of the quantity theorists, I will argue in this lecture, is to dismiss the very reasonable possibility that fiscal policy works because the short-run income elasticity as well as the short-run interest elasticity is low. The first part of this lecture will discuss the theoretical and empirical merits of a short-run money demand function in which the income elasticity of demand is low. The third equation of the Sargent model is the aggregate supply schedule. According to this equation the supply of goods (and implicitly of labour too) depends upon the gap between actual prices and expected prices. Actual prices (and wages) are determined in such a way that goods and labour markets clear. The greater is the excess of actual over expected prices, the greater will be aggregate supply, since unexpected price changes are mistakenly interpreted as relative price changes. Unemployment in excess of the natural rate can persist only so long as the time it takes market participants to formulate their expectations correctly. The second part of this lecture takes issue with this view on empirical grounds; for it is shown that most unemployment belongs to spells of

[1]  J. Gray On Indexation and Contract Length , 1978, Journal of Political Economy.

[2]  George A. Akerlof,et al.  The Implicit Contract Theory of Unemployment meets the Wage Bill Argument , 1980 .

[3]  Robert J. Barro,et al.  A General Disequilibrium Model of Income and Employment , 1971 .

[4]  Brian G. M. Main,et al.  Unemployment spells and unemployment experience , 1980 .

[5]  Thomas J. Sargent,et al.  Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment , 1973 .

[6]  Robert E. Hall,et al.  The Rigidity of Wages and the Persistence of Unemployment , 1975 .

[7]  Nathan Keyfitz,et al.  Applied Mathematical Demography , 1978 .

[8]  Stephen M. Goldfeld,et al.  The Demand for Money Revisited , 1973 .

[9]  K. Clark,et al.  Labor Force Transitions and Unemployment , 1978 .

[10]  Edmund S. Phelps,et al.  Money-Wage Dynamics and Labor-Market Equilibrium , 1968, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  D. Laidler The Rate of Interest and the Demand for Money--Some Empirical Evidence , 1966, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  William J. Baumol,et al.  The Transactions Demand for Cash: An Inventory Theoretic Approach , 1952 .

[13]  Stanley Fischer,et al.  Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule , 1977, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  Peter B. Doeringer,et al.  Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis , 2020 .

[15]  A. Sen,et al.  Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory , 1977 .

[16]  J. Keynes,et al.  The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. , 1936 .

[17]  S. Salant Search theory and duration data: a theory of sorts , 1977 .

[18]  G. Chow On the Long-Run and Short-Run Demand for Money , 1966, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  J. Hicks The crisis in Keynesian economics , 1974 .

[20]  H. Barger The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money , 1936, Nature.

[21]  Oliver E. Williamson,et al.  Understanding the employment relation: the analysis of idiosyncratic exchange , 1975 .

[22]  The Short Run Demand for Money , 1980 .

[23]  H. G. Brown,et al.  The Purchasing Power Of Money , 1911 .

[24]  James Tobin,et al.  The Interest-Elasticity of Transactions Demand For Cash , 1956 .

[25]  R. Lucas,et al.  Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation , 1969, Journal of Political Economy.

[26]  R. Hall Turnover in the Labor Force , 1972 .

[27]  Herschel I. Grossman Why Does Aggregate Employment Fluctuate , 1979 .

[28]  M. Feldstein Lowering the Permanent Rate of Unemployment. , 1973 .

[29]  J. Hicks,et al.  The Crisis in Keynesian Economics. , 1976 .

[30]  Merton H. Miller,et al.  A Model of the Demand for Money by Firms , 1966 .

[31]  G. Perry Unemployment Flows in the U.S. Labor Market , 1972 .