Voters' power in voting games with abstention: Influence relation and ordinal equivalence of power theories

The influence relation was introduced by Isbell [Isbell, J.R., 1958. A class of simple games. Duke Math. J. 25, 423-439] to qualitatively compare the a priori influence of voters in a simple game, which by construction allows only "yes" and "no" votes. We extend this relation to voting games with abstention (VGAs), in which abstention is permitted as an intermediate option between a "yes" and a "no" vote. Unlike in simple games, this relation is not a preorder in VGAs in general. It is not complete either, but we characterize VGAs for which it is complete, and show that it is a preorder whenever it is complete. We also compare the influence relation with recent generalizations to VGAs of the Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf-Coleman power indices [Felsenthal, D.S., Machover, M., 1997. Ternary voting games. Int. J. Game Theory 26, 335-351; Freixas, J., 2005a. The Shapley-Shubik power index for games with several levels of approval in the input and output. Dec. Support Systems 39, 185-195; Freixas, J., 2005b. The Banzhaf index for games with several levels of approval in the input and output. Ann. Operations Res. 137, 45-66]. For weakly equitable VGAs, the influence relation is a subset of the preorderings defined by these two power theories. We characterize VGAs for which the three relations are equivalent.

[1]  Taylor Alan,et al.  Weighted Voting, Multicameral Representation, and Power , 1993 .

[2]  Joël Moulen,et al.  Ordinal equivalence of power notions in voting games , 2002 .

[3]  L. Penrose The Elementary Statistics of Majority Voting , 1946 .

[4]  Alan D. Taylor,et al.  Mathematics and politics : strategy, voting, power and proof , 1997 .

[5]  Dan S. Felsenthal,et al.  Voting power measurement: a story of misreinvention , 2005, Soc. Choice Welf..

[6]  Josep Freixas,et al.  The Shapley-Shubik power index for games with several levels of approval in the input and output , 2005, Decis. Support Syst..

[7]  Josep Freixas,et al.  Weighted voting, abstention, and multiple levels of approval , 2003, Soc. Choice Welf..

[8]  Lawrence Diffo Lambo,et al.  Pouvoir mesuré et capacité d'un électeur à influencer le résultat du vote , 2004 .

[9]  Josep Freixas,et al.  Banzhaf Measures for Games with Several Levels of Approval in the Input and Output , 2005, Ann. Oper. Res..

[10]  Ron Johnston,et al.  On the Measurement of Power: Some Reactions to Laver , 1978 .

[11]  P. Fishburn The Theory Of Social Choice , 1973 .

[12]  Edward M. Bolger,et al.  Characterizations of two power indices for voting games with r alternatives , 2002, Soc. Choice Welf..

[13]  Edward W. Packel,et al.  A new index of power for simplen-person games , 1978 .

[14]  M. Allingham,et al.  Economic power and values of games , 1975 .

[15]  Lawrence Diffo Lambo,et al.  Quel pouvoir mesure-t-on dans un jeu de vote ? , 2000 .

[16]  D. Lepelley,et al.  La mesure du pouvoir de vote , 2003 .

[17]  Martin Shubik,et al.  A Method for Evaluating the Distribution of Power in a Committee System , 1954, American Political Science Review.

[18]  Y. Tomiyama Simple game, voting representation and ordinal power equivalence , 1987 .

[19]  D. Rae,et al.  Decision-Rules and Individual Values in Constitutional Choice , 1969, American Political Science Review.

[20]  E. Packel,et al.  Power, luck and the right index , 1983 .

[21]  Dan S. Felsenthal,et al.  Ternary voting games , 1997, Int. J. Game Theory.

[22]  Sven Berg,et al.  On Voting Power Indices and a Class of Probability Distributions: With applications to EU data , 1999 .

[23]  J. R. Isbell,et al.  A class of simple games , 1958 .

[24]  Ariel Rubinstein,et al.  Stability of decision systems under majority rule , 1980 .

[25]  M. Maschler,et al.  A characterization, existence proof and dimension bounds for the kernel of a game. , 1966 .

[26]  Josep M. Colomer,et al.  Measuring parliamentary deviation , 1996 .