Loss Aversion and the Uniform Pricing Puzzle for Vertically Differentiated Products

The uniform pricing puzzle for vertically differentiated products states that a monopolist sells high and low quality products at the same price despite the fact that quality is perfectly observable and that there are no significant costs of adjusting prices. The puzzle is relevant for movies, books, music, and mobile apps, among others. We show that the puzzle can be resolved by accounting for consumer loss aversion in monetary and consumption utilities and by assuming that consumers face a random utility shock. The novelty of our approach is that the reference transaction is endogenously set as part of a `personal equilibrium' and includes only past purchases of products of the same quality.

[1]  Alan T. Sorensen,et al.  Resale and Rent-Seeking: An Application to Ticket Markets* , 2014 .

[2]  Devin G. Pope,et al.  Is Tiger Woods Loss Averse? Persistent Bias in the Face of Experience, Competition, and High Stakes , 2009 .

[3]  David Huffman,et al.  Reference Points and Effort Provision , 2009, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[4]  S. Rosen,et al.  Monopoly and product quality , 1978 .

[5]  Mario Pagliero,et al.  The Pricing of Art and the Art of Pricing: Pricing Styles in the Concert Industry , 2012 .

[6]  Proliferation of Brewers’ Brands and Price Uniformity in Canadian Beer Markets , 2013 .

[7]  D. Ariely,et al.  When Do Losses Loom Larger than Gains? , 2005 .

[8]  Liran Einav,et al.  Uniform Prices for Differentiated Goods: The Case of the Movie-Theater Industry , 2007 .

[9]  Robin Lindsey,et al.  State-dependent congestion pricing with reference-dependent preferences , 2011 .

[10]  K. Moorthy Market Segmentation, Self-Selection, and Product Line Design , 1984 .

[11]  M. Peitz,et al.  Competition under Consumer Loss Aversion , 2014 .

[12]  Ioana Popescu,et al.  Dynamic Pricing with Loss Averse Consumers and Peak-End Anchoring , 2010, Oper. Res..

[13]  A. Tversky,et al.  Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model , 1991 .

[14]  David Card,et al.  Family Violence and Football: The Effect of Unexpected Emotional Cues on Violent Behavior , 2009, The quarterly journal of economics.

[15]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  The Impact of Consumer Loss Aversion on Pricing , 2004 .

[16]  Yuxin Chen,et al.  The Benefit of Uniform Price for Branded Variants , 2012, Mark. Sci..

[17]  M. Rabin,et al.  A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences , 2006 .

[18]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  Regular Prices and Sales , 2010 .

[19]  B. Kőszegi,et al.  Competition and Price Variation When Consumers Are Loss Averse , 2008 .

[20]  D. Kahneman,et al.  CHAPTER EIGHT. Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market , 2004 .

[21]  Garrett J. van Ryzin,et al.  Revenue Management Under a General Discrete Choice Model of Consumer Behavior , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[22]  Daniel Schunk,et al.  Expectations as Reference Points: Field Evidence from Professional Soccer , 2014, Manag. Sci..

[23]  Benjamin Shiller,et al.  Music for a Song: An Empirical Look at Uniform Pricing and its Alternatives , 2011 .

[24]  Alan T. Sorensen,et al.  Bundle-Size Pricing as an Approximation to Mixed Bundling , 2011 .

[25]  To Price Discriminate or Not: Product Choice and the Selection Bias Problem , 2003 .

[26]  D. Kahneman,et al.  The Boundaries of Loss Aversion , 2005 .

[27]  Fabian Herweg,et al.  Uncertain Demand, Consumer Loss Aversion, and Flat-Rate Tariffs , 2011 .

[28]  Keith M. Marzilli Ericson,et al.  Expectations as Endowments: Evidence on Reference-Dependent Preferences from Exchange and Valuation Experiments , 2010 .

[29]  Jeffrey C. Ely,et al.  Optimal Contracts for Loss Averse Consumers , 2012 .

[30]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Reference-Dependent Consumption Plans , 2009 .

[31]  Jidong Zhou,et al.  Reference Dependence and Market Competition , 2008 .