Industrial and Corporate Change Advance Access published February 3, 2006

Co-design by a firm and its suppliers has become a widely accepted means of developing new products, especially technologically-complex products. Much existing research emphasizes stable and trusting relationships as a "one-best way" for governing these co-design relations. This article questions this view. The article argues that co-design relations are likely to be diverse, unstable, and conflictual due to the inherent nature of the co-design activity. The inherent diversity of co-design relations is explained by the need to organize for distinct coordination needs. Three coordination processes, each directed toward a different coordination need, are derived from the study of a single aerospace co-design project. Interactions between these processes are shown to systematically produce conflict and instability in co-design relations. The main implication of the study is that co-design performance depends on a firm and its suppliers dealing explicitly with these interactions but that there is no "one-best way" of doing so. Copyright 2006, Oxford University Press.

[1]  Susan Helper,et al.  Strategy and Irreversibility in Supplier Relations: The Case of the U.S. Automobile Industry , 1991, Business History Review.

[2]  Robert P. Smith,et al.  A predictive model of sequential iteration in engineering design , 1997 .

[3]  Jonathan Zeitlin,et al.  Governing Decentralized Production: Institutions, Public Policy, and the Prospects for Inter-firm Collaboration in US Manufacturing , 2004 .

[4]  Mary Ann Glynn,et al.  Creativity and technological learning: the roles of organization architecture and crisis in large-scale projects , 2000 .

[5]  Donald Gerwin,et al.  Coordinating New Product Development in Strategic Alliances , 2004 .

[6]  R. Gulati,et al.  The Architecture of Cooperation: Managing Coordination Costs and Appropriation Concerns in Strategic Alliances , 1998 .

[7]  Todd R. Zenger,et al.  Do Formal Contracts and Relational Governance Function as Substitutes or Complements , 2002 .

[8]  Jules Townshend,et al.  Power, A Radical View , 2007 .

[9]  S. Borgatti,et al.  A General Theory of Network Governance: Exchange Conditions and Social Mechanisms , 1997 .

[10]  Charles F. Sabel,et al.  Pragmatic Collaborations: Advancing Knowledge While Controlling Opportunism , 2000 .

[11]  H. Demsetz,et al.  Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization , 1975, IEEE Engineering Management Review.

[12]  T. Nishiguchi,et al.  Strategic Industrial Sourcing: The Japanese Advantage , 1994 .

[13]  Adler,et al.  Flexibility versus efficiency? A case study of model changeovers in the Toyota production system , 1999 .

[14]  C. Perrow Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay , 1975 .

[15]  Jay R. Galbraith Competing with flexible lateral organizations , 1993 .

[16]  Michael Burda,et al.  Revolutionizing product development , 1993 .

[17]  David Robertson,et al.  Product development performance: Strategy, organization, and management in the world auto industry , 1992 .

[18]  Mitsuo Nagamachi,et al.  Supplier involvement in automotive component design: are there really large US Japan differences? , 1996 .

[19]  A. Griffin PDMA Research on New Product Development Practices: Updating Trends and Benchmarking Best Practices , 1997 .

[20]  K. Pavitt,et al.  Knowledge Specialization, Organizational Coupling, and the Boundaries of the Firm: Why Do Firms Know More than They Make? , 2001 .

[21]  A. Strauss Basics Of Qualitative Research , 1992 .

[22]  Kim B. Clark,et al.  Architectural Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Failure of , 1990 .

[23]  O. Williamson,et al.  STRATEGY RESEARCH: GOVERNANCE AND COMPETENCE PERSPECTIVES , 1999 .

[24]  D. Dougherty Interpretive Barriers to Successful Product Innovation in Large Firms , 1992 .

[25]  Rajan R. Kamath,et al.  Strategic Industrial Sourcing. The Japanese Advantage , 1995 .

[26]  G. Herrigel Emerging Strategies and Forms of Governance in High-Wage Component Manufacturing Regions , 2004 .

[27]  Christina L. Ahmadjian,et al.  Keiretsu, Governance, and Learning: Case Studies in Change from the Japanese Automotive Industry , 2000 .

[28]  B. Uzzi,et al.  Social Structure and Competition in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of Embeddedness , 1997 .

[29]  Barry Boehm,et al.  Spiral Development: Experience, Principles, and Refinements , 2000 .

[30]  Yasunori Baba,et al.  Towards knowledge-based product development: the 3-D CAD model of knowledge creation , 1998 .

[31]  Vincent Frigant L'impact de la production modulaire sur l'approfondissement de la Division Internationale des Processus Productifs (DIPP) , 2007 .

[32]  Jeffrey H. Dyer Specialized supplier networks as a source of competitive advantage : Evidence from the auto industry , 1996 .

[33]  Akira Takeishi,et al.  Bridging inter‐ and intra‐firm boundaries: management of supplier involvement in automobile product development , 2001 .

[34]  S. Wheelwright,et al.  The interaction of design hierarchies and market concepts in technological evolution * , 2003 .

[35]  Christoph H. Loch,et al.  Exchanging Preliminary Information in Concurrent Engineering: Alternative Coordination Strategies , 2002, Organ. Sci..

[36]  K. Eisenhardt,et al.  PRODUCT DEVELOPMENT: PAST RESEARCH, PRESENT FINDINGS, AND FUTURE DIRECTIONS , 1995 .

[37]  Danny Miller,et al.  The Icarus Paradox: How Exceptional Companies Bring About Their Own Downfall , 1990 .