Market responses to qualitative information from a group polarization perspective

Abstract This study examines the predictions of group polarization in response to the receipt of qualitative information (i.e., good or bad news) in a laboratory market. Qualitative information induces varying beliefs within the market because such information is interpreted using the relevant knowledge possessed by the recipients. Findings from the group polarization literature suggest that individuals who subsequently hold the most extreme price beliefs will influence the market to a greater extent than individuals holding the most conservative beliefs. Group polarization research also suggests that participation in a market will accentuate risk preferences so that good news produces a cautious shift in prices (i.e., towards lower prices) whereas bad news produces a risky shift (i.e., towards higher prices). The results confirm the predictions of group polarization and further suggest that if extreme reactions to information reflect recency, so too may the market price.

[1]  R. Thaler,et al.  Does the Stock Market Overreact , 1985 .

[2]  Lawrence Harris,et al.  Optimal Dynamic Order Submission Strategies In Some Stylized Trading Problems , 1998 .

[3]  Johannes A. Zuber,et al.  Group decision, choice shift, and polarization in consulting, political, and local political scenarios: An experimental investigation and theoretical analysis , 1991 .

[4]  Anat Barnir,et al.  Can Group-and Issue-Related Factors Predict Choice Shift? , 1998 .

[5]  R. Thaler,et al.  Further Evidence On Investor Overreaction and Stock Market Seasonality , 1987 .

[6]  S. Kiesler,et al.  Group processes in computer-mediated communication☆ , 1986 .

[7]  Jay F. Nunamaker,et al.  Lessons from a Dozen Years of Group Support Systems Research: A Discussion of Lab and Field Findings , 1996, J. Manag. Inf. Syst..

[8]  H. Lamm,et al.  Risky shift as a function of group members' value of risk and need for approval , 1971 .

[9]  Colin Camerer,et al.  The Disposition Effect in Securities Trading: An Experimental Analysis , 1991 .

[10]  John C. Easterwood,et al.  Inefficiency in Analysts' Earnings Forecasts: Systematic Misreaction or Systematic Optimism? , 1999 .

[11]  J. Stoner A comparison of individual and group decisions involving risk , 1961 .

[12]  D. Myers,et al.  The group polarization phenomenon. , 1976 .

[13]  Donald V. Moser,et al.  The effects of biases in probability judgments on market prices , 1994 .

[14]  Bernard C. Y. Tan,et al.  Group Polarization and Computer-Mediated Communication: Effects of Communication Cues, Social Presence, and Anonymity , 2002, Inf. Syst. Res..

[15]  Seymour Smidt,et al.  Volume for Winners and Losers: Taxation and Other Motives for Stock Trading , 1986 .

[16]  W. Swap,et al.  Risky shift and social exchange in dyads , 1969 .

[17]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[18]  M. Coller Information, noise, and asset prices: An experimental study , 1996 .

[19]  J. H. Davis,et al.  Some compelling intuitions about group consensus decisions, theoretical and empirical research, and interpersonal aggregation phenomena: Selected examples 1950-1990 , 1992 .

[20]  N. Bateson Familiarization, group discussion, and risk taking , 1966 .

[21]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect Theory : An Analysis of Decision under Risk Author ( s ) : , 2007 .

[22]  A. Vinokur,et al.  Persuasive argumentation and social comparison as determinants of attitude polarization , 1977 .

[23]  External validity and the risky shift: Empirical limits and theoretical implications. , 1974 .

[24]  Lola L. Lopes,et al.  The Role of Aspiration Level in Risky Choice: A Comparison of Cumulative Prospect Theory and SP/A Theory. , 1999, Journal of mathematical psychology.

[25]  Helmut Lamm,et al.  Discussion-induced shift toward higher demands in negotiation† , 1974 .

[26]  Brad Tuttle,et al.  An examination of market efficiency: Information order effects in a laboratory market , 1997 .

[27]  S. Moscovici,et al.  The group as a polarizer of attitudes. , 1969 .

[28]  Peter H. Reingen,et al.  Modeling Individual Preference Evolution and Choice in a Dynamic Group Setting , 1996 .

[29]  R. Baron,et al.  Why do Groups Make Riskier Decisions Than Individuals?1 , 1970 .

[30]  Ajay S. Vinze,et al.  Polarization and Persuasive Argumentation: A Study of Decision Making in Group Settings , 1998, MIS Q..

[31]  Colin Camerer Do Biases in Probability Judgment Matter in Markets? Experimental Evidence , 1987 .

[32]  Anil K. Makhija,et al.  Predicting Contemporary Volume with Historic Volume at Differential Price Levels: Evidence Supporting the Disposition Effect , 1988 .

[33]  Vicky Arnold,et al.  Behavioral accounting research : foundations and frontiers , 1997 .

[34]  Terrance Odean,et al.  Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? , 1996 .

[35]  M. Coller,et al.  The acquisition of price-relevant domain knowledge by a market , 2002 .

[36]  Robert J. Bloomfield,et al.  Disclosure Effects In The Laboratory: Liquidity, Depth, And The Cost Of Capital , 2000 .

[37]  R. Hogarth,et al.  Order effects in belief updating: The belief-adjustment model , 1992, Cognitive Psychology.

[38]  M. Coller,et al.  Do market prices reveal the decision models of sophisticated investors? Evidence from the laboratory , 2004 .

[39]  C. Plott,et al.  Efficiency of Experimental Security Markets with Insider Information: An Application of Rational-Expectations Models , 1982, Journal of Political Economy.

[40]  M. Statman,et al.  The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long , 1985 .

[41]  Steven J. Kachelmeier,et al.  Market Efficiency, Bounded Rationality, and Supplemental Business Reporting Disclosures , 2001 .

[42]  M. W. Nelson,et al.  Communication of Confidence as a Determinant of Group Judgment Accuracy , 1996 .