Estimating the Tradeoff between Risk Protection and Moral Hazard with a Nonlinear Budget Set Model of Health Insurance

Insurance induces a well-known tradeoff between the welfare gains from risk protection and the welfare losses from moral hazard. Empirical work traditionally estimates each side of the tradeoff separately, potentially yielding mutually inconsistent results. I develop a nonlinear budget set model of health insurance that allows for the calculation of both sides of the tradeoff simultaneously, allowing for a relationship between moral hazard and risk protection. An important feature of this model is that it considers nonlinearities in the consumer budget set that arise from deductibles, coinsurance rates, and stoplosses that alter moral hazard as well as risk protection relative to no insurance. I illustrate the properties of my model by estimating it using data on employer sponsored health insurance from a large firm. Within my empirical context, the average deadweight losses from moral hazard substantially outweigh the average welfare gains from risk protection. However, the welfare impact of moral hazard and risk protection are both small relative to transfers from the government through the tax preference for employer sponsored health insurance and transfers from some agents to other agents through a common premium.

[1]  Fabián Duarte Price elasticity of expenditure across health care services. , 2012, Journal of health economics.

[2]  Liran Einav,et al.  Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: How Important is Forward Looking Behavior? , 2012 .

[3]  H. Hong,et al.  Regression Discontinuity Designs with an Endogenous Forcing Variable and an Application to Contracting in Health Care , 2011 .

[4]  J. Gruber,et al.  Medicare Part D and the Financial Protection of the Elderly , 2010 .

[5]  Amanda E. Kowalski,et al.  THE IMPACT OF AN INDIVIDUAL HEALTH INSURANCE MANDATE ON HOSPITAL AND PREVENTIVE CARE: EVIDENCE FROM MASSACHUSETTS , 2010 .

[6]  Jonathan Levin,et al.  Beyond Testing: Empirical Models of Insurance Markets , 2009, Annual review of economics.

[7]  J. Gruber,et al.  Choice Inconsistencies Among the Elderly: Evidence from Plan Choice in the Medicare Part D Program , 2009, The American economic review.

[8]  L. Einav,et al.  Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets Using Variation in Prices , 2008, The quarterly journal of economics.

[9]  A. Gavazza,et al.  Dynamic Inefficiencies in Employment-Based Health Insurance System Theory and Evidence , 2007 .

[10]  M. Feldstein,et al.  Balancing the goals of health care provision and financing. , 2006, Health affairs.

[11]  Jeffrey B. Liebman,et al.  Earnings Responses to Increases in Payroll Taxes , 2006 .

[12]  Anil Kumar,et al.  Employer Matching and 401(K) Saving: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Study , 2006 .

[13]  Anil Kumar Nonparametric Estimation of the Impact of Taxes on Female Labor Supply , 2006 .

[14]  Raj Chetty,et al.  A New Method of Estimating Risk Aversion , 2003 .

[15]  Michael H. Riordan,et al.  Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care , 2002 .

[16]  I Hendel,et al.  Asymmetric information in health insurance: evidence from the National Medical Expenditure Survey. , 2001, The Rand journal of economics.

[17]  Pierre-André Chiappori,et al.  Testing for Asymmetric Information in Insurance Markets , 2000, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  W. Manning,et al.  Health insurance: the tradeoff between risk pooling and moral hazard. , 1996, Journal of health economics.

[19]  S. Blomquist Restrictions in Labor Supply Estimation: Is the MaCurdy Critique Correct? , 1995 .

[20]  M. Feldstein,et al.  A Major Risk Approach to Health Insurance Reform , 1994, Tax Policy and the Economy.

[21]  B. Dowd,et al.  A new estimate of the welfare loss of excess health insurance. , 1991, The American economic review.

[22]  E B Keeler,et al.  The demand for episodes of treatment in the Health Insurance Experiment. , 1988, Journal of health economics.

[23]  E. Keeler,et al.  Health insurance and the demand for medical care: evidence from a randomized experiment. , 1987, The American economic review.

[24]  Randall P. Ellis,et al.  Rational behavior in the presence of coverage ceilings and deductibles , 1986 .

[25]  R. Moffitt,et al.  The Joint Choice of Retirement Age and Postretirement Hours of Work , 1985, Journal of Labor Economics.

[26]  J. Hausman,et al.  The Effect of Taxation on Labor Supply: Evaluating the Gary Negative Income Tax Experiment , 1978, Journal of Political Economy.

[27]  M. Baily Some aspects of optimal unemployment insurance , 1978 .

[28]  Joseph P. Newhouse,et al.  Deductibles and the Demand for Medical Services: The Theory of the Consumer Facing a Variable Price Schedule Under Uncertainty , 1977 .

[29]  M. Hurd THE ESTIMATION OF NONLINEAR LABOR SUPPLY FUNCTIONS WITH TAXES FROM A TRUNCATED SAMPLE , 1976 .

[30]  H. Rosen TAXES IN A LABOR SUPPLY MODEL WITH JOINT WAGE-HOURS DETERMINATION , 1976 .

[31]  M. Feldstein The Welfare Loss of Excess Health Insurance , 1973, Journal of Political Economy.

[32]  I. Ehrlich,et al.  Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection , 1972, Journal of Political Economy.

[33]  John N Friedman,et al.  NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ADJUSTMENT COSTS, FIRM RESPONSES, AND LABOR SUPPLY ELASTICITIES: EVIDENCE FROM DANISH TAX RECORDS , 2010 .

[34]  Joshua Lustig Measuring Welfare Losses from Adverse Selection and Imperfect Competition in Privatized Medicare , 2009 .

[35]  Matthew J. Eichner,et al.  The Demand for Medical Care: What People Pay Does Matter , 1998 .

[36]  Matthew J. Eichner,et al.  Medical expenditures and major risk health insurance , 1997 .

[37]  T. MaCurdy Work Disincentive Effects of Taxes: A Reexamination of Some Evidence , 1992 .