The Gender and Poverty Impacts of Trade Liberalization in Senegal

Developing countries are deeply engaged in trade negotiations at the bilateral, regional and international (WTO) levels. As imports, exports and tariff duties all occupy an important part of their economies, far-reaching impacts on production, labor and capital markets, household incomes and, perhaps most importantly, economic growth will indubitably ensue. As men and women occupy very different roles in these economies, particularly in terms of the import and export orientation of the sectors in which they work, they will be affected very differently by these reforms. To anticipate these changes, a dynamic economy-wide model is developed with an application to Senegal. Whereas most similar existing studies consider the comparative static resource reallocation effects of trade reforms, ours is the first to focus on the growth effects (“dynamic gains from trade”), which are thought to be possibly much larger. The trade-productivity link is revealed to be the strongest growth channel, raising GDP by over three percentage points by the end of our 15 year simulation period. Trade liberalization is found to increase the gender wage gap in favor of men, especially among unskilled workers, as men are more active in export-oriented sectors such as cash crops and mining whereas women contribute more to import-competing sectors such as food crops. Furthermore, the ensuing growth effects further widen the over-all gender wage gap, as the productivity gains from increased openness are greatest in female-intensive sectors in which imports rise markedly. Thus, this suggests the need to implement policies aimed at increasing both unskilled and skilled women’s exposure in labor-intensive export industries, which is currently male dominated. A linked microsimulation analysis, based on a survey of Senegalese households, show that trade liberalization reduces poverty in Senegal, particularly in rural areas. While the fall in the relative wages of rural workers would initially lead us to believe that rural households would lose the most from trade liberalization, they are in fact compensated by greater consumer price savings, given that they consume more goods from the initially protected agricultural and agro-industrial sectors.

[1]  John Cockburn,et al.  Libéralisation commerciale et pauvreté en Afrique , 2010 .

[2]  M. Mikić Future trade research areas that matter to developing country policymakers , 2007 .

[3]  S. Robinson,et al.  Economy-Wide and Distributional Impacts of an Oil Price Shock on the South African Economy , 2007 .

[4]  Q. Wodon,et al.  Has Growth in Senegal After the 1994 Devaluation Been Pro-Poor? , 2007 .

[5]  J. Cockburn,et al.  Trade Liberalization and Poverty - Lessons from Asia and Africa , 2007 .

[6]  Johan F.M. Swinnen,et al.  Trade, Standards, and Poverty: Evidence from Senegal , 2006 .

[7]  P. Gustafsson,et al.  Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth , 2006 .

[8]  Lucia Savard Analyse de la pauvreté et distribution de revenus dans le cadre de la modélisation en équilibre général calculable , 2006 .

[9]  R. Baldwin,et al.  No 727 June 2006 Trade and Growth with Heterogeneous Firms , 2006 .

[10]  R. Baldwin Heterogeneous Firms and Trade: Testable and Untestable Properties of the Melitz Model , 2005 .

[11]  J. Cockburn,et al.  Trade Liberalisation, Growth and Poverty in Senegal: A Dynamic Microsimulation Cge Model Analysis , 2005 .

[12]  Frédéric Robert-Nicoud,et al.  Trade and Growth with Heterogenous Firms , 2005 .

[13]  F. Bourguignon,et al.  The microeconomics of income distribution dynamics: in East Asia and Latin America , 2004 .

[14]  M. Ravallion,et al.  Gainers and Losers from Trade Reform in Morocco , 2004 .

[15]  S. Onyeiwu,et al.  Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in Africa , 2004 .

[16]  L. Winters Trade Liberalisation and Economic Performance: An Overview , 2004 .

[17]  E. Helpman,et al.  Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms , 2004 .

[18]  Onathan,et al.  Plants and Productivity in International Trade , 2004 .

[19]  L. Christiaensen,et al.  Child Growth, Shocks, and Food Aid in Rural Ethiopia. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. , 2003 .

[20]  A. Diagne,et al.  Pauvreté et distribution de revenus au Sénégal: une approche par la modélisation en équilibre général calculable micro-simulé , 2003 .

[21]  E. Asiedu On the Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment to Developing Countries: Is Africa Different? , 2001 .

[22]  S. Robinson,et al.  Crisis and Income Distribution: A Micro-Macro Model for Indonesia , 2001 .

[23]  David L. Dollar,et al.  Growth is Good for the Poor , 2001 .

[24]  Euysung Kim Trade liberalization and productivity growth in Korean manufacturing industries: price protection, market power, and scale efficiency , 2000 .

[25]  Wolfgang Keller,et al.  How Trade Patterns and Technology Flows Affect Productivity Growth , 1997 .

[26]  Graham,et al.  The Theory of International Trade , 1989 .

[27]  Kar-yiu Wong Are international trade and factor mobility substitutes , 1986 .

[28]  J. Markusen,et al.  Trade in Goods and Factors with International Differences in Technology , 1983 .

[29]  Uka Ezenwe Trade and growth in West Africa in the 1980s , 1982, The Journal of Modern African Studies.

[30]  J. Agarwal,et al.  Determinants of foreign direct investment: A survey , 1980 .

[31]  G. Haberler The theory of international trade , 1936 .