When a 12.86% Mortality is More Dangerous than 24.14%: Implications for Risk Communication

SUMMARY Participants assessed the riskiness of 11 well-known causes of death. Each participant was presented with an estimation of the number of deaths in the population due to that particular cause. The estimates were obtained from a previous study of naive participants’ intuitive estimations. For instance, based on the result of the previous study, the number of deaths due to cancer was presented as: ‘2,414 out of 10,000’, ‘1,286 out of 10,000’, ‘24.14 out of 100’ and ‘12.86 out of 100’. The estimates of deaths were presented in analogous ways for the remaining ten causes of death. It was hypothesized that the judged degree of riskiness is affected by the number of deaths, irrespective of the total possible number (such as 10,000 or 100). Results from Experiment 1 were consistent with this prediction. Participants rated cancer as riskier when it was described as ‘kills 1,286 out of 10,000 people’ than as ‘kills 24.14 out of 100 people’, and similar results were observed regarding the remaining 10 causes of death. Experiment 2 replicated this trend. Implications for risk communications are discussed. & 1997 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

[1]  Yoav Ganzach,et al.  Preference Reversals in Equal‐probability Gambles: A Case for Anchoring and Adjustment , 1996 .

[2]  Kimihiko Yamagishi,et al.  Consistencies and Biases in Risk Perception: I. Anchoring Process and Response-Range Effect , 1994 .

[3]  Kimihiko Yamagishi Consistencies and Biases in Risk Perception: II. Individual Subjects' Performance , 1994 .

[4]  Dale T. Miller,et al.  The framing of relative performance feedback: Seeing the glass as half empty or half full. , 1994 .

[5]  S. Epstein,et al.  Conflict Between Intuitive and Rational Processing: When People Behave Against Their Better Judgment , 1994 .

[6]  L. Myaskovsky,et al.  The Easy Path From Many To Much: the Numerosity Heuristic , 1994, Cognitive Psychology.

[7]  Anchoring Effects on Judgement, Estimation, and Discrimination of Numerosity , 1994, Perceptual and motor skills.

[8]  S. Epstein,et al.  Conflict between intuitive and rational processing: when people behave against their better judgment. , 1994, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[9]  P Slovic,et al.  Perceived risk, stigma, and potential economic impacts of a high-level nuclear waste repository in Nevada. , 1991, Risk analysis : an official publication of the Society for Risk Analysis.

[10]  H. J. Einhorn,et al.  Expression theory and the preference reversal phenomena. , 1987 .

[11]  M. Hewstone,et al.  Bias in the use of base rates: Racial prejudice in decision‐making , 1988 .

[12]  Baruch Fischhoff,et al.  Judged Lethality: How Much People Seem to Know Depends Upon How They Are Asked , 1983 .

[13]  P. Slovic,et al.  Preference Reversals: A Broader Perspective , 1983 .

[14]  B. Fischhoff,et al.  Lay Foibles and Expert Fables in Judgments about Risk , 1982 .

[15]  H. Shaklee,et al.  A rule analysis of judgments of covariation between events , 1980, Memory & cognition.

[16]  J. Tukey,et al.  Variations of Box Plots , 1978 .

[17]  I. Ajzen Intuitive theories of events and the effects of base-rate information on prediction. , 1977 .

[18]  A. Tversky,et al.  Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases , 1974, Science.

[19]  A. Tversky,et al.  On the psychology of prediction , 1973 .

[20]  H. Lindman Inconsistent preferences among gambles. , 1971 .

[21]  P. Slovic,et al.  Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. , 1971 .

[22]  J. Smedslund THE CONCEPT OF CORRELATION IN ADULTS , 1963 .