Mathematical models for social group behavior

In this paper, we seek to identity how mathematical and economic analysis can be used to gain insights about the mutation of social groups. Group mutability has been studied in multiple domains, with insights generated on significant factors at differing scales. Mathematical modeling enables the simultaneous study of such phenomena, understanding interactions and generating hypotheses for experiments. In particular, we focus on group fracture, where individuals leave groups of which they are members. For example, this can be due to perceived differences with other group members due to norm related conflict (such as extreme actions by some members). Our aim is to consider simple mathematical models incorporating a selection of social and psychological theory which describes these phenomena as a way to understand their interplay, and describe the trade-offs and challenges. This will help a federation model the behavior of extremist groups, and determine not only when an intervention is necessary, but also the best course of action to take to induce the fracture of such groups. This paper is an exploratory investigation into methods of achieving this goal and evaluating the usefulness of the outputs to federations.

[1]  Martha Crenshaw,et al.  Theories of terrorism: Instrumental and organizational approaches , 1987 .

[2]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The evolution of cooperation. , 1984, Science.

[3]  M. Brewer,et al.  Self-evaluation effects of interpersonal versus intergroup social comparison. , 1994, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[4]  Gavin Pearson,et al.  Intra-group Tension Under Inter-group Conflict: A Generative Model Using Group Social Norms and Identity , 2017, AHFE.

[5]  D. C. Feldman,et al.  The Development and Enforcement of Group Norms , 1984 .

[6]  Michael Lewis Bernard,et al.  Using Computational Modeling to Examine Shifts Towards Extremist Behaviors in European Diaspora Communities , 2017 .

[7]  A. Barabasi,et al.  Quantifying social group evolution , 2007, Nature.

[8]  John C. Turner,et al.  Self-categorization theory and social influence. , 1989 .

[9]  D. Friedman On economic applications of evolutionary game theory , 1998 .

[10]  E. Fehr,et al.  Altruistic punishment in humans , 2002, Nature.

[11]  L. Festinger A Theory of Social Comparison Processes , 1954 .

[12]  M. Nowak Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation , 2006, Science.

[13]  Cristina Bicchieri,et al.  Norms in the Wild: How to Diagnose, Measure, and Change Social Norms , 2016 .

[14]  D. Nettle Social Markers and the Evolution of Reciprocal Exchange , 1997, Current Anthropology.

[15]  Karen S. Cook,et al.  Generalized Exchange and Social Dilemmas , 1993 .

[16]  Gavin Pearson,et al.  A generative model for predicting terrorist incidents , 2017, Defense + Security.

[17]  Davide Massaro,et al.  Fairness Norms and Theory of Mind in an Ultimatum Game: Judgments, Offers, and Decisions in School-Aged Children , 2014, PloS one.

[18]  H. Gintis,et al.  Costly signaling and cooperation. , 2001, Journal of theoretical biology.

[19]  J. Elster Social Norms and Economic Theory , 1989, Handbook of Monetary Policy.

[20]  U. Fischbacher,et al.  Social norms and human cooperation , 2004, Trends in Cognitive Sciences.

[21]  Stuart M. Allen,et al.  A Dominant Social Comparison Heuristic Unites Alternative Mechanisms for the Evolution of Indirect Reciprocity , 2016, Scientific Reports.

[22]  K. Lewin Frontiers in Group Dynamics , 1947 .

[23]  T. Wills Downward Comparison Principles in Social Psychology , 1981 .

[24]  Stuart M. Allen,et al.  Cooperation through self-similar social networks , 2010, TAAS.

[25]  R. Collins For Better or Worse: The Impact of Upward Social Comparison on Self-Evaluations , 1996 .

[26]  Kathleen M. Carley A Theory of Group Stability , 1991 .

[27]  Xuanming Su,et al.  Optimal Design of Social Comparison Effects: Setting Reference Groups and Reference Points , 2013, Manag. Sci..

[28]  A. Oswald,et al.  Comparison-concave utility and following behaviour in social and economic settings , 1998 .

[29]  George A. Akerlof,et al.  Economics and Identity , 2000 .

[30]  Christian H. Jordan,et al.  Motivation by positive or negative role models: regulatory focus determines who will best inspire us. , 2002, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[31]  David G. Rand,et al.  Intuition, deliberation, and the evolution of cooperation , 2016, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[32]  Y. Miyashita,et al.  Two distinct neural mechanisms underlying indirect reciprocity , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[33]  Shelley E. Taylor,et al.  The affective consequences of social comparison: either direction has its ups and downs. , 1990, Journal of personality and social psychology.

[34]  Rachel E. Kranton,et al.  Identity Economics 2016: Where Do Social Distinctions and Norms Come From? , 2016 .

[35]  R. Axelrod An Evolutionary Approach to Norms , 1986, American Political Science Review.

[36]  Richard Sosis,et al.  Stability of Groups with Costly Beliefs and Practices , 2011, J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul..

[37]  J. Turner Social categorization and the self-concept: A social cognitive theory of group behavior. , 2010 .

[38]  Bruce Edmonds,et al.  Applying a socially inspired technique (tags) to improve cooperation in P2P networks , 2005, IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics - Part A: Systems and Humans.