Store brand introduction and quantity decision under asymmetric cost information in a retailer-led supply chain

Abstract The paper focuses on the topic of introducing store brands under asymmetric cost information in a retailer-dominant supply chain. We assume that the manufacturer privately knows the production cost for national brands, while the retailer only knows the distribution of the cost information. There exists a signal game between the manufacturer and the retailer after introducing store brands. In such case, when the true production cost for national brands is high, the manufacturer has to distort downward the production quantity to make the retailer believe the production cost is indeed high. Such distortion may amplify double marginalization. As a result, the retailer becomes worse off while the manufacturer becomes better/worse off from introducing store brands. In addition, the manufacturer does not share information to the retailer without introducing store brands, while the manufacturer may prefer to sharing information to the retailer with introducing store brands.

[1]  Ronald T. Wilcox,et al.  Private-Labels and the Channel Relationship: A Cross-Category Analysis , 1998 .

[2]  Guiomar Martín-Herrán,et al.  Fighting store brands through the strategic timing of pricing and advertising decisions , 2019, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[3]  Sungchul Choi,et al.  Price competition and store competition: Store brands vs. national brand , 2013, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[4]  Qihui Lu,et al.  Impact of fairness concern on retailer-dominated supply chain , 2020, Comput. Ind. Eng..

[5]  S. X. Zhu,et al.  Strategic interplay between store brand introduction and online direct channel introduction , 2018, Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review.

[6]  Trichy V. Krishnan,et al.  Guaranteed profit margins : A demonstration of retailer power , 1997 .

[7]  Manu Goyal,et al.  Strategic Information Management Under Leakage in a Supply Chain , 2009, Manag. Sci..

[8]  Bin Liu,et al.  Pricing decisions in a dual channels system with different power structures , 2011, ICSSSM11.

[9]  Terry A. Taylor,et al.  Incentives for Retailer Forecasting: Rebates vs. Returns , 2009, Manag. Sci..

[10]  Wansheng Tang,et al.  Supply chain contract design of procurement and risk-sharing under random yield and asymmetric productivity information , 2018, Comput. Ind. Eng..

[11]  Song Huang,et al.  Information acquisition and transparency in a supply chain with asymmetric production cost information , 2016 .

[12]  S. C. Choi,et al.  Price Competition in a Channel Structure with a Common Retailer , 1991 .

[13]  Koen Pauwels,et al.  Who Benefits from Store Brand Entry , 2004 .

[14]  Suresh Radhakrishnan,et al.  Private Label Vendor Selection in a Supply Chain: Quality and Clientele Effects , 2010 .

[15]  Arcan Nalca,et al.  Brand positioning and consumer taste information , 2018, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[16]  Eunkyu Lee,et al.  Effect of Store Brand Introduction on Channel Price Leadership: An Empirical Investigation , 2017 .

[17]  R. Lal,et al.  Building Store Loyalty through Store Brands , 2000 .

[18]  Prasad A. Naik,et al.  The effects of expert quality evaluations versus brand name on price premiums , 2003 .

[19]  S. Sethi,et al.  Contracting and Coordination Under Asymmetric Production Cost Information , 2010 .

[21]  Maosen Zhou,et al.  Supply chain coordination with information sharing: The informational advantage of GPOs , 2017, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[22]  Zongsheng Huang,et al.  Money-back guarantee and pricing decision with retailer's store brand , 2020 .

[23]  Hans Sebastian Heese,et al.  Supply chain interactions due to store-brand introductions: The impact of retail competition , 2010, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[24]  Hans Sebastian Heese,et al.  Competing with channel partners: Supply chain conflict when retailers introduce store brands , 2010 .

[25]  Zhuoxin Li,et al.  Supplier Encroachment under Asymmetric Information , 2012, Manag. Sci..

[26]  Scott A. Neslin,et al.  Pursuing the Value-Conscious Consumer: Store Brands versus National Brand Promotions , 2001 .

[27]  R. Staelin,et al.  Vertical Strategic Interaction: Implications for Channel Pricing Strategy , 1997 .

[28]  Jun Zhang,et al.  Does a Store Brand Always Hurt the Manufacturer of a Competing National Brand? , 2015 .

[29]  Raj Sethuraman,et al.  Assessing the External Validity of Analytical Results from National Brand and Store Brand Competition Models , 2009, Mark. Sci..

[30]  John A. Quelch,et al.  Brands Versus Private Labels: Fighting to Win , 1996 .

[31]  Hongtao Zhang,et al.  Supply Chain Information Sharing in a Competitive Environment , 2002 .

[32]  Hua Ke,et al.  How does store-brand introduction affect a supply chain with uncertain information? , 2018, J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst..

[33]  Jagmohan S. Raju,et al.  The introduction and performance of store brands , 1995 .

[34]  Barton A. Weitz,et al.  Supply Chain Management and Retailer Performance: Emerging Trends, Issues, and Implications for Research and Practice , 2009 .

[35]  William P. Putsis,et al.  Assessing the Competitive Interaction Between Private Labels and National Brands , 1999 .

[36]  X. Guan,et al.  Retailer Information Sharing with Supplier Encroachment , 2017 .

[37]  Wansheng Tang,et al.  Information sharing and information concealment in the presence of a dominant retailer , 2018, Comput. Ind. Eng..

[38]  J. Tarziján Should national brand manufacturers produce private labels , 2007 .

[39]  Bintong Chen,et al.  Supply chain coordination with customer returns and retailer's store brand product , 2018, International Journal of Production Economics.

[40]  David E. Mills Why Retailers Sell Private Labels , 1995 .

[41]  Gérard P. Cachon,et al.  Contracting to Assure Supply: How to Share Demand Forecasts in a Supply Chain , 2001, Manag. Sci..