Estimating the residual demand curve facing a single firm

This paper presents an econometric technique for estimating the single firm residual demand curve that does not require the estimation of demand cross-elasticities. The technique is particularly suited for the estimation of firm market power in product differentiated industries, where cross-elasticities are notoriously difficult to measure. One estimated parameter is directly related to a firm's markup of price over marginal cost when product differentiation is extensive, when an industry consists of a dominant firm and a price-taking fringe, when a Consistent Conjectures Equilibrium is the correct oligopoly solution concept, when firms are Stackelberg leaders relative to their environment, or when firms are perfect competitors. The estimates can indicate power over price in other circumstances. An instrumental variables technique is employed, using firm-individuated factor prices to identify firm-specific residual demand. Yet even when instruments are unavailable, the technique produces elasticity estimates biased in the conservative direction of disproving market power. This methodology is applied to estimate the market power of three firms in an industry characterized by product differentiation: brewing. Over our 1962–82 sample period, Pabst and Coors had similar national market shares and each had high shares in several states. Yet Pabst was virtually a price-taker while Coors possessed substantial market power. Anheuser-Busch had market power in the early part of the sample, but little after 1975 when Miller Brewing changed the competitive nature of the industry.

[1]  Hugo Sonnenschein,et al.  The Dual of Duopoly Is Complementary Monopoly: or, Two of Cournot's Theories Are One , 1968, Journal of Political Economy.

[2]  Frederic M. Scherer,et al.  The Economics of Multi-Plant Operation. , 1977 .

[3]  J. Baker,et al.  The Gains from Merger or Collusion in Product-differentiated Industries , 1985 .

[4]  D. Jorgenson,et al.  The Role of Capital in U.S. Economic Growth, 1948-1979 , 1980 .

[5]  Gyoichi Iwata,et al.  Measurement of Conjectural Variations in Oligopoly , 1974 .

[6]  R. Posner,et al.  Market Power in Antitrust Cases , 1981 .

[7]  E. Appelbaum Testing price taking behavior , 1979 .

[8]  I. Horowitz,et al.  Firms in a Declining Market: The Brewing Case , 1965 .

[9]  D. Sumner Measurement of Monopoly Behavior: An Application to the Cigarette Industry , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[10]  Timothy F. Bresnahan,et al.  Duopoly Models with Consistent Conjectures , 1981 .

[11]  T. Bresnahan Departures from marginal-cost pricing in the American automobile industry: Estimates for 1977–1978 , 1981 .

[12]  James N Rosse,et al.  ESTIMATING COST FUNCTION PARAMETERS WITHOUT USING COST DATA: ILLUSTRATED METHODOLOGY , 1970 .

[13]  T. Bresnahan Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: The 1955 Price War , 1987 .

[14]  Ragnar Frisch,et al.  A Complete Scheme for Computing all Direct and Cross Demand Elasticities in a Model with many Factors , 1959 .

[15]  W. David Kelton,et al.  ADVERTISING AND INTRAINDUSTRY BRAND SHIFT IN THE U.S. BREWING INDUSTRY , 1982 .

[16]  Mark J. Roberts,et al.  Firm interdependence in oligopolistic markets , 1979 .

[17]  Alan O. Sykes,et al.  Herfindahl Concentration, Rivalry, and Mergers , 1982 .

[18]  P. T. Spiller,et al.  Geographic Market Definition under the U. S. Department of Justice Merger Guidelines , 1987, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[19]  I. Horowitz,et al.  The beer industry , 1967 .

[20]  T. Hogarty,et al.  The Demand for Beer , 1972 .

[21]  E. Appelbaum The estimation of the degree of oligopoly power , 1982 .

[22]  D. F. Greer Production Differentiation and Concentration in the Brewing Industry , 1971 .

[23]  A. Lerner The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power , 1934 .