Fixed-to-mobile call substitution and telephony market definition in Korea

An appropriate market definition is critical in most antitrust cases. In practice, antitrust authorities define economic markets in a deterministic manner with little concern about the risk involved in defining markets incorrectly. In contrast, this article proposes a probabilistic market definition method by which antitrust authorities can establish a statistical confidence level for their intended market-definition judgments. As an application, we examine the likelihood that the fixed-line and mobile telephony services in Korea can compete in the same economic market. Combining critical loss analysis with a hierarchical Bayes model for stated preference data, we find some evidence for the separation of the fixed-line and mobile telephony markets in present-day Korea. After discussing certain possible regulation biases for market definition, we predict that the two markets will converge in the near future as the mobile price premium continues to decrease.

[1]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Marketing models of consumer heterogeneity , 1998 .

[2]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  A Bayesian analysis of the multinomial probit model with fully identified parameters , 2000 .

[3]  Kamel Jedidi,et al.  A Hierarchical Bayesian Methodology for Treating Heterogeneity in Structural Equation Models , 2000 .

[4]  Ingo Vogelsang,et al.  The relationship between mobile and fixed-line communications: A survey , 2010, Inf. Econ. Policy.

[5]  Dennis L. Weisman WHEN CAN REGULATION DEFER TO COMPETITION FOR CONSTRAINING MARKET POWER?: COMPLEMENTS AND CRITICAL ELASTICITIES , 2006 .

[6]  D. Rubin,et al.  Inference from Iterative Simulation Using Multiple Sequences , 1992 .

[7]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Bayesian Statistics and Marketing: Rossi/Bayesian Statistics and Marketing , 2006 .

[8]  J. Carroll,et al.  Guest Editorial: Psychometric Methods in Marketing Research: Part I, Conjoint Analysis , 1995 .

[9]  Michael R. Ward,et al.  Usage Substitution between Fixed and Mobile Telephony in the U.S. , 2004 .

[10]  Greg M. Allenby,et al.  Using Extremes to Design Products and Segment Markets , 1995 .

[11]  D. Carlton,et al.  Market Definition: Use and Abuse , 2013 .

[12]  J. Douglas Carroll,et al.  Psychometric Methods in Marketing Research: Part I, Conjoint Analysis , 1995 .

[13]  Is fixed-mobile substitution strong enough to de-regulate fixed voice telephony? Evidence from the Austrian markets , 2011 .

[14]  Nakil Sung,et al.  Substitution between Mobile and Fixed Telephones in Korea , 2002 .

[15]  Chi-Kuo Mao,et al.  FMS patterns: Penetration vs. traffic substitution in different groups of countries , 2008 .

[16]  Peter E. Rossi,et al.  Bayesian Statistics and Marketing , 2005 .

[17]  T. Valletti,et al.  Mobile Termination: What is the “Right” Charge?* , 2005 .

[18]  Christopher Podmore Information economics and policy: In the United States edited by Michael Rubin Libraries Unlimited, Littleton, CO 1983, 340 pp , 1984 .

[19]  Z. John Zhang,et al.  Augmenting Conjoint Analysis to Estimate Consumer Reservation Price , 2002, Manag. Sci..

[20]  Greg M. Allenby,et al.  A Choice Model with Conjunctive, Disjunctive, and Compensatory Screening Rules , 2004 .

[21]  Christine Zulehner,et al.  Demand estimation and market definition for broadband Internet services , 2009 .

[22]  Michael R. Ward,et al.  Going Mobile: Substitutability Between Fixed and Mobile Access , 2003 .

[23]  Quantifying price-driven wireless substitution in telephony , 2011 .

[24]  Paul Beaudry Wireline deregulation: The Canadian experience , 2010 .

[25]  Karen L. Soderberg,et al.  Wireless substitution: state-level estimates from the National Health Interview Survey, January-December 2007. , 2009, National health statistics reports.