On the benefits of being constrained when receiving signals

We study a Bayesian persuasion setting in which the receiver is trying to match the (binary) state of the world. The sender’s utility is partially aligned with the receiver’s, in that conditioned on the receiver’s action, the sender derives higher utility when the state of the world matches the action. Our focus is on whether in such a setting, being constrained helps a receiver. Intuitively, if the receiver can only take the sender’s preferred action with smaller probability, the sender might have to reveal more information, so that the receiver can take the action more specifically when the sender prefers it. We show that with a binary state of the world, this intuition indeed carries through: under very mild non-degeneracy conditions, a more constrained receiver will always obtain (weakly) higher utility than a less constrained one. Unfortunately, without additional assumptions, the result does not hold when there are more than two states in the world, which we show with an explicit example.

[1]  Stephen Morris,et al.  Information Design: A Unified Perspective , 2019 .

[2]  J. Sobel,et al.  STRATEGIC INFORMATION TRANSMISSION , 1982 .

[3]  M. Spence Job Market Signaling , 1973 .

[4]  Andriy Zapechelnyuk,et al.  Persuasion of a Privately Informed Receiver , 2016 .

[5]  Jonas Hedlund,et al.  Persuasion with communication costs , 2015, Games Econ. Behav..

[6]  Tristan Tomala,et al.  Persuasion with limited communication capacity , 2019, J. Econ. Theory.

[7]  D. Bergemann,et al.  Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information , 2011 .

[8]  Eran Shmaya,et al.  The Interval Structure of Optimal Disclosure , 2019, Econometrica.

[9]  Emir Kamenica,et al.  Bayesian Persuasion , 2009 .

[10]  Haifeng Xu,et al.  Algorithmic Bayesian persuasion , 2015, STOC.

[11]  Matthew Gentzkow,et al.  Costly Persuasion , 2013 .

[12]  Demosthenis Teneketzis,et al.  Dynamic Information Design: A Simple Problem on Optimal Sequential Information Disclosure , 2021, Dynamic Games and Applications.

[13]  A. Ambrus,et al.  Multi-sender cheap talk with restricted state spaces , 2008 .

[14]  Demosthenis Teneketzis,et al.  Dynamic Information Design: A Simple Problem on Optimal Sequential Information Disclosure , 2020, Dynamic Games and Applications.

[15]  Eduardo Perez-Richet,et al.  Interim Bayesian Persuasion: First Steps , 2014 .

[16]  Delphine Prady,et al.  Complicating to Persuade , 2011 .

[17]  Anton Kolotilin Experimental design to persuade , 2015, Games Econ. Behav..

[18]  Shaddin Dughmi,et al.  Persuasion with Limited Communication , 2016, EC.

[19]  Elias Carroni,et al.  Does Costly Persuasion Signal Quality? , 2020 .

[20]  Emir Kamenica,et al.  Bayesian Persuasion and Information Design , 2019, Annual Review of Economics.

[21]  Inbal Talgam-Cohen,et al.  Bayesian Persuasion under Ex Ante and Ex Post Constraints , 2020, ArXiv.

[22]  Tristan Tomala,et al.  Persuasion with Limited Communication Capacity , 2017, J. Econ. Theory.

[23]  A. Kolotilin Optimal Information Disclosure: A Linear Programming Approach , 2016 .

[24]  Reduced Form Information Design: Persuading a Privately Informed Receiver , 2020 .

[25]  Sanford J. Grossman The Informational Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product Quality , 1981, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[26]  Ludmila Matyskova,et al.  Bayesian Persuasion with Costly Information Acquisition , 2018 .

[27]  Raphael Boleslavsky,et al.  Bayesian Persuasion and Moral Hazard , 2018 .

[28]  Anh Nguyen,et al.  Bayesian persuasion with costly messages , 2021, J. Econ. Theory.

[29]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications , 1981 .

[30]  D. Bergemann,et al.  Bayes Correlated Equilibrium and the Comparison of Information Structures in Games , 2013 .