Algorithmic Game Theory

The Price of Anarchy in Bilateral Network Formation in an Adversary Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 267 Lasse Kliemann The Query Complexity of Correlated Equilibria . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 268 Sergiu Hart and Noam Nisan The Money Pump as a Measure of Revealed Preference Violations . . . . . 269 Bart Smeulders, Laurens Cherchye, Bram De Rock, and Frits C.R. Spieksma Author Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 271 The Complexity of Fully Proportional Representation for Single-Crossing Electorates Piotr Skowron, Lan Yu, Piotr Faliszewski, and Edith Elkind 1 University of Warsaw, Poland 2 Nanyang Technological University, Singapore 3 AGH University of Science and Technology, Poland Abstract. We study the complexity of winner determination in single-crossing elections under two classic fully proportional representation rules—Chamberlin– Courant’s rule and Monroe’s rule. Winner determination for these rules is known to be NP-hard for unrestricted preferences. We show that for single-crossing preferences this problem admits a polynomial-time algorithm for Chamberlin– Courant’s rule, but remains NP-hard for Monroe’s rule. Our algorithm for Chamberlin–Courant’s rule can be modified to work for elections with bounded singlecrossing width. To circumvent the hardness result for Monroe’s rule, we consider single-crossing elections that satisfy an additional constraint, namely, ones where each candidate is ranked first by at least one voter (such elections are called narcissistic). For single-crossing narcissistic elections, we provide an efficient algorithm for the egalitarian version of Monroe’s rule. We study the complexity of winner determination in single-crossing elections under two classic fully proportional representation rules—Chamberlin– Courant’s rule and Monroe’s rule. Winner determination for these rules is known to be NP-hard for unrestricted preferences. We show that for single-crossing preferences this problem admits a polynomial-time algorithm for Chamberlin– Courant’s rule, but remains NP-hard for Monroe’s rule. Our algorithm for Chamberlin–Courant’s rule can be modified to work for elections with bounded singlecrossing width. To circumvent the hardness result for Monroe’s rule, we consider single-crossing elections that satisfy an additional constraint, namely, ones where each candidate is ranked first by at least one voter (such elections are called narcissistic). For single-crossing narcissistic elections, we provide an efficient algorithm for the egalitarian version of Monroe’s rule.

[1]  Archie C. Chapman,et al.  On the Existence of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria in Integer-Splittable Weighted Congestion Games , 2011, SAGT.

[2]  R. Tyrrell Rockafellar,et al.  Coherent Approaches to Risk in Optimization Under Uncertainty , 2007 .

[3]  Max Klimm,et al.  On the Existence of Pure Nash Equilibria in Weighted Congestion Games , 2010, Math. Oper. Res..

[4]  I. Milchtaich,et al.  Congestion Games with Player-Specific Payoff Functions , 1996 .

[5]  Ludovic Renou,et al.  Minimax Regret and Strategic Uncertainty , 2008, J. Econ. Theory.

[6]  Angelo Fanelli,et al.  Efficient Computation of Approximate Pure Nash Equilibria in Congestion Games , 2011, 2011 IEEE 52nd Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science.

[7]  Martin Gairing,et al.  Exact Price of Anarchy for Polynomial Congestion Games , 2006, STACS.

[8]  Yossi Azar,et al.  The Price of Routing Unsplittable Flow , 2005, STOC '05.

[9]  I-Tang Yu,et al.  The rise of cooperation in correlated matching prisoners dilemma: An experiment , 2007 .

[10]  Elias Koutsoupias,et al.  The price of anarchy of finite congestion games , 2005, STOC '05.

[11]  Michael P. Wellman,et al.  Autonomous bidding agents - strategies and lessons from the trading agent competition , 2007 .

[12]  Evdokia Nikolova,et al.  Stochastic Selfish Routing , 2011, SAGT.

[13]  D. Stahl,et al.  Experimental evidence on players' models of other players , 1994 .

[14]  Itai Ashlagi,et al.  Resource selection games with unknown number of players , 2006, AAMAS '06.

[15]  R. Trivers The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism , 1971, The Quarterly Review of Biology.

[16]  R. Rosenthal A class of games possessing pure-strategy Nash equilibria , 1973 .

[17]  Nicholas R. Jennings,et al.  TRAVOS: Trust and Reputation in the Context of Inaccurate Information Sources , 2006, Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems.

[18]  Berthold Vöcking,et al.  On the Impact of Combinatorial Structure on Congestion Games , 2006, FOCS.

[19]  Amos Fiat,et al.  When the Players Are Not Expectation Maximizers , 2010, SAGT.

[20]  N. Stier-Moses,et al.  Wardrop Equilibria with Risk-Averse Users , 2010 .

[21]  Moshe Tennenholtz,et al.  Competitive Safety Analysis: Robust Decision-Making in Multi-Agent Systems , 2002, J. Artif. Intell. Res..

[22]  Ioannis Caragiannis,et al.  Tight Bounds for Selfish and Greedy Load Balancing , 2006, ICALP.

[23]  Paul G. Spirakis,et al.  Selfish Unsplittable Flows , 2004, ICALP.

[24]  Kevin Leyton-Brown,et al.  Beyond equilibrium: predicting human behaviour in normal form games , 2010, AAAI.

[25]  Dimitris Fotakis Congestion Games with Linearly Independent Paths: Convergence Time and Price of Anarchy , 2009, Theory of Computing Systems.

[26]  Jeff S. Shamma,et al.  Risk sensitivity of price of anarchy under uncertainty , 2013, EC '13.

[27]  Robert W. Rosenthal,et al.  The network equilibrium problem in integers , 1973, Networks.

[28]  Steve Chien,et al.  Convergence to approximate Nash equilibria in congestion games , 2007, SODA '07.