On sequential and simultaneous contributions under incomplete information

When contributors to a common cause (or public good) are uncertain about each others’ valuations, early contributors are likely to be cautious in free-riding on future contributors. Contrary to the case of complete information, when contributors have independent private valuations for the public good, the expected total contribution generated in a sequential move game may be higher than in a simultaneous move game. This is established in a conventional framework with quasi-linear utility where agents care only about the total provision of the public good (rather than individual contribution levels) and there is no non-convexity in the provision of the public good. We allow for arbitrary number of agents and fairly general distribution of types.

[1]  T. Groves,et al.  Optimal Allocation of Public Goods: A Solution to the 'Free Rider Problem' , 1977 .

[2]  J. Andreoni Toward a Theory of Charitable Fundraising , 1998 .

[3]  William T. Harbaugh What do donations buy?: A model of philanthropy based on prestige and warm glow , 1998 .

[4]  Eric Maskin,et al.  Sequential Innovation, Patents, and Imitation , 2000 .

[5]  Chaim Fershtman,et al.  Dynamic voluntary provision of public goods , 1991 .

[6]  Murali Agastya,et al.  Cheap talk, efficiency and egalitarian cost sharing in joint projects , 2007, Games Econ. Behav..

[7]  B. Nalebuff,et al.  Dragon-slaying and ballroom dancing: The private supply of a public good , 1984 .

[8]  Jacques Cremer,et al.  A Sequential Solution to the Public Goods Problem , 1985 .

[9]  Brit Grosskopf,et al.  Simultaneous versus sequential public good provision and the role of refunds -- An experimental study , 2009 .

[10]  Fernando Vega-Redondo,et al.  Public subscription and private contributions , 1995 .

[11]  Ronald S. Drabman,et al.  An investigation of pledging behavior to a national charitable telethon , 1984 .

[12]  Lise Vesterlund,et al.  The informational value of sequential fundraising , 2003 .

[13]  Eyal Winter,et al.  Optimal incentives for sequential production processes , 2006 .

[14]  K. Bagwell Commitment and observability in games , 1995 .

[15]  Adriaan Soetevent,et al.  Anonymity in giving in a natural context-a field experiment in thirty churches , 2005 .

[16]  Amihai Glazer,et al.  A Signaling Explanation for Charity , 1996 .

[17]  David Lucking-Reiley,et al.  The Effects of Seed Money and Refunds on Charitable Giving: Experimental Evidence from a University Capital Campaign , 2002, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  Anat R. Admati,et al.  Joint Projects without Commitment , 1991 .

[19]  Huseyin Yildirim,et al.  Why charities announce donations: a positive perspective , 2001 .

[20]  Leslie M. Marx,et al.  Dynamic Voluntary Contribution to a Public Project , 2000 .

[21]  Flavio M. Menezes,et al.  Private provision of discrete public goods with incomplete information , 2001 .

[22]  Santanu Roy,et al.  Repeated Charitable Contributions Under Incomplete Information , 2008 .

[23]  Neil Bruce,et al.  Defence Expenditures by Countries in Allied and Adversarial Relationships , 1990 .

[24]  M. Agastya Transparency of peer activities confounds cheap talk in joint projects. , 2009 .

[25]  Matthew O. Jackson,et al.  Implementing a public project and distributing its cost , 1992 .

[26]  H. Varian Sequential contributions to public goods , 1994 .

[27]  Mark Gradstein,et al.  Time Dynamics and Incomplete Information in the Private Provision of Public Goods , 1992, Journal of Political Economy.

[28]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  Private incentives in social dilemmas: The effects of incomplete information and altruism , 1988 .

[29]  Adriaan R. Soetevent,et al.  Anonymity in Giving in a Natural Context : A Field Experiment in 30 Churches , 2005 .

[30]  Barton L. Lipman,et al.  Provision of Public Goods: Fully Implementing the Core through Private Contributions , 1989 .

[31]  L. Vesterlund,et al.  After You - Endogenous Sequencing in Voluntary Contribution Games , 2005 .