Advertising and Political Expenditures in a Spatial Election Game: An Experimental Investigation

Most researchers agree that the role of money in politics is important, however, there is no agreement on the extent to which money influences electoral outcomes and governmental policies. One reason for this discord is that the existing research concentrates on aggregate level studies. Therefore, this literature cannot tell us anything about the effects of money on individual decision-making. Only recently have spatial models, which examine the interactions of individual decisions within an institutional context, begun to consider the importance of money and politics. However, as the case with most spatial models, there are no existing "real-world " data to test the hypotheses that are derived. Consequently, researchers have relied on laboratory experiments to test the robustness of these models. This essay presents a series of experiments that examine the effects of advertising and political contributions in a sequential spatial election game, given that candidates have equal resources and their positions are fixed. These conditions model the classical prisoner's dilemma game in which both candidates would be better off if they cooperated and choose not to advertise. The results showed that candidates who advertised the most, generally won the most elections.

[1]  David Austen-Smith,et al.  Interest groups, campaign contributions, and probabilistic voting , 1987 .

[2]  Kenneth C. Williams,et al.  Retrospective voting: An experimental study , 1987 .

[3]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  A Theory of Electoral Equilibrium: A Spatial Analysis Based on the Theory of Games , 1973, The Journal of Politics.

[4]  W. Brock,et al.  Tariff Formation in a Democracy , 1980 .

[5]  S. Glantz,et al.  Election Outcomes: Whose Money Matters? , 1976, Journal of Politics.

[6]  R. McKelvey,et al.  Two-Candidate Elections without Majority Rule Equilibria , 1982 .

[7]  J. Oppenheimer,et al.  Universalism in Experimental Committees , 1982, American Political Science Review.

[8]  Shmuel Nitzan,et al.  Directional and local electoral equilibria with probabilistic voting , 1981 .

[9]  M. Hinich,et al.  An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process , 1970, American Political Science Review.

[10]  H. Chappell Campaign Contributions and Congressional Voting: A Simultaneous Probit-Tobit Model , 1982 .

[11]  Kristian S. Palda The Effect of Expenditure on Political Success , 1975, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[12]  V. Smith Papers in experimental economics , 1991 .

[13]  W. Welch Money and votes: A simultaneous equation model , 1981 .

[14]  Charles R. Plott,et al.  Committee Decisions under Majority Rule: An Experimental Study , 1978, American Political Science Review.

[15]  Benjamin I. Page The Theory of Political Ambiguity , 1976, American Political Science Review.

[16]  Michael C. Munger,et al.  Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented , 1986, American Political Science Review.

[17]  Melvin J. Hinich,et al.  SOCIAL PREFERENCE ORDERINGS AND MAJORITY RULE , 1972 .

[18]  Kenneth C. Williams,et al.  The rationally uninformed electorate: Some experimental evidence , 1989 .

[19]  B. Bental,et al.  Political contribution and policy — Some extensions , 1975 .

[20]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  A Decade of Experimental Research on Spatial Models of Elections and Committees , 1990 .

[21]  Melvin J. Hinich,et al.  Nonspatial Candidate Characteristics and Electoral Competition , 1982, The Journal of Politics.

[22]  G. Jacobson,et al.  Money and votes reconsidered: congressional elections, 1972–1982 , 1985 .

[23]  Jeffrey S. Banks,et al.  A model of electoral competition with incomplete information , 1990 .

[24]  A. Wilhite,et al.  Labor PAC contributions and labor legislation: A simultaneous logit approach , 1987 .

[25]  D. Wittman Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[26]  J. Snyder Election Goals and the Allocation of Campaign Resources , 1989 .

[27]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  Elections with limited information: A fulfilled expectations model using contemporaneous poll and endorsement data as information sources , 1985 .

[28]  K. Shepsle The Strategy of Ambiguity: Uncertainty and Electoral Competition , 1972, American Political Science Review.

[29]  Donald C. Keenan,et al.  A General Equilibrium Model of Congressional Voting , 1982 .

[30]  J. Grenzke PACs and the Congressional Supermarket: The Currency is Complex , 1989 .

[31]  David P. Baron,et al.  Service-Induced Campaign Contributions and the Electoral Equilibrium , 1989 .

[32]  Rick K. Wilson Results on the Condorcet Winner , 1986 .

[33]  Paul H. Rubin,et al.  Congressman, Constituents, and Contributors , 1982 .

[34]  W. Crain,et al.  Campaign Expenditures and Political Competition , 1976, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[35]  J. R. Wright PACs, Contributions, and Roll Calls: An Organizational Perspective , 1985, American Political Science Review.

[36]  A. Smithies Optimum Location in Spatial Competition , 1941, Journal of Political Economy.

[37]  G. Jacobson,et al.  The Effects of Campaign Spending in Congressional Elections , 1978, American Political Science Review.

[38]  Melvin J. Hinich,et al.  Equilibrium in spatial voting: The median voter result is an artifact , 1977 .

[39]  G. Durden,et al.  Determining Legislative Preferences on the Minimum Wage: An Economic Approach , 1976, Journal of Political Economy.

[40]  Peter C. Ordeshook,et al.  Sequential elections with limited information , 1985 .

[41]  John O. Ledyard,et al.  The pure theory of large two-candidate elections , 1984 .

[42]  R. Barro The control of politicians: An economic model , 1973 .

[43]  R. Calvert Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidate Motivations, Uncertainty, and Convergence* , 1985 .