A Theory of Endogenous Commitment

Commitment is typically modelled by assigning to one of the players the ability to take an initial binding action. The weakness of this approach is that the fundamental question of who has the opportunity to commit cannot be addressed, as it is assumed. This paper presents a framework in which commitment power arises endogenously from the fundamentals of the model. We construct a finite dynamic game in which players are given the option to change their minds as often as they wish, but pay a switching cost if they do so. We show that for games with two players and two actions there is a unique subgame-perfect equilibrium with a simple structure. This equilibrium is independent of the order and timing of moves and is robust to other protocol specifications. Moreover, despite the perfect information nature of the model and the costly switches, strategic delays may arise in equilibrium. The flexibility of the model allows us to apply it to various environments. In particular, we study an entry deterrence situation. Its equilibrium is intuitive and illustrative of how commitment power is endogenously determined. Copyright 2008, Wiley-Blackwell.

[1]  Eric van Damme,et al.  Commitment Robust Equilibria and Endogenous Timing , 1996 .

[2]  R. Barro The control of politicians: An economic model , 1973 .

[3]  Roger Lagunoff,et al.  Asynchronous Choice in Repeated Coordination Games , 1997 .

[4]  B. Douglas Bernheim,et al.  Bequests as Signals: An Explanation for the Equal Division Puzzle , 2000, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  Robert W. Rosenthal,et al.  A note on robustness of equilibria with respect to commitment opportunities , 1991 .

[6]  Steven A. Matthews,et al.  Refining cheap-talk equilibria , 1991 .

[7]  A. Rubinstein Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model , 1982 .

[8]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Preemption and Rent Equalization in the Adoption of New Technology , 1985 .

[9]  J. Ferejohn Incumbent performance and electoral control , 1986 .

[10]  Vijay Krishna,et al.  The art of conversation: eliciting information from experts through multi-stage communication , 2004, J. Econ. Theory.

[11]  K. Judd Credible Spatial Preemption , 1985 .

[12]  Anat R. Admati,et al.  Joint Projects without Commitment , 1991 .

[13]  David Strömberg,et al.  Optimal Campaigning in Presidential Elections: The Probability of Being Florida , 2002 .

[14]  Giovanni Maggi,et al.  Endogenous Leadership in a New Market , 1996 .

[15]  Jeffrey S. Banks,et al.  A model of electoral competition with incomplete information , 1990 .

[16]  T. Schelling,et al.  The Strategy of Conflict. , 1961 .

[17]  A. Alesina Credibility and Policy Convergence in a Two-party System with Rational Voters , 1988 .

[18]  R. Schmalensee Entry Deterrence in the Ready-to-Eat Breakfast Cereal Industry , 1978 .

[19]  Douglas Gale,et al.  Monotone Games with Positive Spillovers , 2001, Games Econ. Behav..

[20]  Abhinay Muthoo,et al.  A Bargaining Model Based on the Commitment Tactic , 1996 .

[21]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Reputation and imperfect information , 1982 .

[22]  P. Ghemawat,et al.  Airbus vs. Boeing in Superjumbos: A Case of Failed Preemption , 2002 .

[23]  Barton L. Lipman,et al.  Switching Costs in Frequently Repeated Games , 2000, J. Econ. Theory.

[24]  Joachim Henkel,et al.  The 1.5th Mover Advantage , 2002 .

[25]  Douglas Gale,et al.  Dynamic coordination games , 1995 .

[26]  Garth Saloner,et al.  Cournot duopoly with two production periods , 1987 .

[27]  A. Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy , 1957 .

[28]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Predation, reputation, and entry deterrence☆ , 1982 .

[29]  T. Schelling The Strategy of Conflict , 1963 .