A Game Theory Warning to Blind Drivers Playing Chicken With Public Goods

We develop a game theoretic model of the role of foresight in games involving users interacting over a public good. Previous research in this area has applied game theory to understand social dilemmas and inform policy initiatives. However, considerations of the “evolving structure” of natural resource games over time and agents' planning horizon raises the complexity of game analysis substantially and has often been overlooked. We analyze a simple model of an irrigation system shared by two users and consider how players will act under different levels of foresight. Without foresight into game changes over time, players are blind to the fact that they are in a game of chicken. We model agents with foresight by interconnecting games across time and show how this creates opportunities for “strategic loss” early on, allowing players with foresight to reduce total costs. High future costs can thus be avoided with foresight if the rising costs of inaction are made apparent. We consider the effect of discounting and differences between players to provide policy recommendations regarding incentives for foresight.

[1]  G. Hardin,et al.  The Tragedy of the Commons , 1968, Green Planet Blues.

[2]  J. M. Smith,et al.  The Logic of Animal Conflict , 1973, Nature.

[3]  A. Rubinstein Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model , 1982 .

[4]  J. Vickers Signalling in a Model of Monetary Policy with Incomplete Information , 1986 .

[5]  M. Reisner Cadillac Desert: The American West and Its Disappearing Water , 1987 .

[6]  W. Baumol,et al.  The theory of environmental policy: On the theory of externalities , 1988 .

[7]  P. Micklin Desiccation of the Aral Sea: A Water Management Disaster in the Soviet Union , 1988, Science.

[8]  Dilip Abreu On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting , 1988 .

[9]  K. Hipel,et al.  Conflict models in graph form: Solution concepts and their interrelationships , 1989 .

[10]  G. Brady Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action , 1993 .

[11]  Henricus Emerence David Houba Game theoretic models of bargaining , 1994 .

[12]  Tom Gilb,et al.  Interactive Decision Making: The Graph Model for Conflict Resolution , 1994 .

[13]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  The Folk Theorem for Repeated Games with Discounting and Incomplete Information , 1998 .

[14]  François Bousquet,et al.  Agent-Based modelling, game theory and natural resource management issues , 2001 .

[15]  John C. Harsanyi,et al.  Games with Incomplete Information Played by "Bayesian" Players, I-III: Part I. The Basic Model& , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[16]  Richard E. Just,et al.  Implications of “victim pays” infeasibilities for interconnected games with an illustration for aquifer sharing under unequal access costs , 2004 .

[17]  E. Ostrom Understanding Institutional Diversity , 2005 .

[18]  Keith W. Hipel,et al.  The Graph Model for Conflict Resolution: Past, Present, and Future , 2005 .

[19]  R. Bissoli,et al.  Water Framework Directive 2000/60/EC. , 2008 .

[20]  M. Mew A black swan? , 2009, BDJ.

[21]  Kaveh Madani,et al.  Game theory and water resources , 2010 .

[22]  D. Lettenmaier,et al.  On the causes of the shrinking of Lake Chad , 2010 .

[23]  W. Powell,et al.  Institutions , 2010 .

[24]  Vincent Marchau,et al.  Addressing deep uncertainty using adaptive policies: introduction to section 2 , 2010 .

[25]  D. Liefferink,et al.  The EU Water Framework Directive: A multi-dimensional analysis of implementation and domestic impact , 2011 .

[26]  Keith W. Hipel,et al.  Non-Cooperative Stability Definitions for Strategic Analysis of Generic Water Resources Conflicts , 2011 .

[27]  R. Spiegler Bounded Rationality and Industrial Organization , 2011 .

[28]  J. Paavola Climate change : the ultimate ‘ tragedy of the commons ’ ? , 2011 .

[29]  K. Madani Hydropower licensing and climate change: Insights from cooperative game theory , 2011 .

[30]  Arild Underdal,et al.  The Effectiveness of International Environmental Regimes: Comparing and Contrasting Findings from Quantitative Research , 2011 .

[31]  J. Lund,et al.  California’s Sacramento–San Joaquin Delta Conflict: From Cooperation to Chicken , 2012 .

[32]  A. Dinar,et al.  Non-cooperative institutions for sustainable common pool resource management: Application to groundwater , 2012 .

[33]  Li An,et al.  Modeling human decisions in coupled human and natural systems: Review of agent-based models , 2012 .

[34]  A. Dinar,et al.  Cooperative institutions for sustainable common pool resource management: Application to groundwater , 2012 .

[35]  A. Perea Epistemic Game Theory: Reasoning and Choice , 2012 .

[36]  K. Madani Modeling international climate change negotiations more responsibly: Can highly simplified game theory models provide reliable policy insights? , 2013 .

[37]  Warren E. Walker,et al.  Dynamic adaptive policy pathways: A method for crafting robust decisions for a deeply uncertain world , 2013 .

[38]  Yi Tao,et al.  The replicator equation and other game dynamics , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[39]  Mahboubeh Zarezadeh,et al.  The significance of game structure evolution for deriving game-theoretic policy insights , 2014, 2014 IEEE International Conference on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics (SMC).

[40]  K. Madani,et al.  Successful Collaborative Negotiation over Water Policy: Substance versus Process , 2015 .

[41]  Kaveh Madani,et al.  A game theory-reinforcement learning (GT-RL) method to develop optimal operation policies for multi-operator reservoir systems , 2014 .

[42]  K. Madani Water management in Iran: what is causing the looming crisis? , 2014, Journal of Environmental Studies and Sciences.

[43]  John M. Anderies,et al.  Effect of infrastructure design on commons dilemmas in social−ecological system dynamics , 2015, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[44]  O. Bens,et al.  Society - Water - Technology: A Critical Appraisal of Major Water Engineering Projects , 2015 .

[45]  K. Madani,et al.  Aral Sea syndrome desiccates Lake Urmia: Call for action , 2015 .

[46]  Joseph R. Kasprzyk,et al.  Many-objective optimization and visual analytics reveal key trade-offs for London's water supply , 2015 .

[47]  M. Podimata,et al.  Evolution of Game Theory Application in Irrigation Systems , 2015 .

[48]  Jonathan D. Herman,et al.  How should robustness be defined for water systems planning under change , 2015 .

[49]  K. Madani,et al.  Iran’s Socio-economic Drought: Challenges of a Water-Bankrupt Nation , 2016 .

[50]  J. Lund,et al.  Game theory and risk‐based leveed river system planning with noncooperation , 2016 .

[51]  P. Micklin The future Aral Sea: hope and despair , 2016, Environmental Earth Sciences.

[52]  Giangiacomo Bravo,et al.  Managing the commons: a simple model of the emergence of institutions through collective action , 2016 .

[53]  A. Malkawi,et al.  Reclaiming the Dead Sea: Alternatives for Action , 2016 .

[54]  N. Oreskes,et al.  Assessing ExxonMobil’s climate change communications (1977–2014) , 2017 .

[55]  K. Madani Radicals running riot , 2018, New Scientist.

[56]  Jay R. Lund,et al.  Adaptive water infrastructure planning for nonstationary hydrology , 2018, Advances in Water Resources.

[57]  K. Madani,et al.  Decision making under deep uncertainty for adapting urban drainage systems to change , 2018, Urban Water Journal.

[58]  R. Stone An Iranian researcher went home to serve his country. Now, ‘I realize that I’m lucky I’m not in prison.’ , 2018 .

[59]  G. Destouni,et al.  Climatic or regionally induced by humans? Tracing hydro-climatic and land-use changes to better understand the Lake Urmia tragedy , 2019, Journal of Hydrology.