Supply Chain Relationships and Contracts: The Impact of Repeated Interaction on Capacity Investment and Procurement

Consider a firm that is developing a highly innovative product. Producing the product requires that an upstream supplier invest in production capacity well in advance. Because the product is ill-defined at the time when the supplier initiates his capacity investment, the firms are unable to write court-enforceable contracts that specify the terms of trade. The supplier faces a classic hold up problem. When the firms finally do negotiate the terms of trade, his cost of capacity will be sunk (irrelevant). Anticipating this, the supplier will underinvest in capacity. However, with repeated new product introduction and capacity investment, the firms may adopt informal terms of trade: The buyer promises to purchase at a price that reflects the cost of capacity, and the supplier increases his capacity investment. The value of future cooperation creates an incentive for the buyer to pay the supplier as promised. Assuming symmetric information about demand, capacity and production costs, we derive optimal informal terms of trade that are appealingly simple. Then, assuming that the buyer cannot observe the supplier's capacity investment and the supplier cannot observe the buyer's demand, we compare the performance of informal price-only and quantity commitment agreements. If the production cost is low and either the capacity cost is low or the discount factor is high, then the buyer should promise to purchase a specific quantity rather than simply promise to pay a per unit price; otherwise, the buyer should simply promise to pay a specified unit price.

[1]  J. Nash THE BARGAINING PROBLEM , 1950, Classics in Game Theory.

[2]  Z. A. Lomnicki,et al.  Mathematical Theory of Reliability , 1966 .

[3]  B. Klein,et al.  Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process , 1978, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[4]  R. Myerson Incentive Compatibility and the Bargaining Problem , 1979 .

[5]  O. Williamson Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations , 1979, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[6]  A. Rubinstein Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model , 1982 .

[7]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration , 1986 .

[8]  O. Hart,et al.  Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation , 1988 .

[9]  Dilip Abreu On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting , 1988 .

[10]  O. Hart,et al.  Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm , 1988, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  E. Stacchetti,et al.  Towards a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games with Imperfect Monitoring , 1990 .

[12]  M. Whinston,et al.  Incomplete Contracts, Vertical Integration, and Supply Assurance , 1993 .

[13]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with Funding from Working Paper Department of Economics the Folk Theorem with Imperfect Public Information , 2022 .

[14]  Curtis R. Taylor,et al.  Competition or Compensation: Supplier Incentives Under the American and Japanese Subcontracting Systems , 1997 .

[15]  E. Fehr,et al.  Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: experimental evidence , 1997 .

[16]  J. H. Dyer Effective interim collaboration: how firms minimize transaction costs and maximise transaction value , 1997 .

[17]  Kevin J. Murphy,et al.  Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm , 1997 .

[18]  G. Ryzin,et al.  On the Relationship Between Inventory Costs and Variety Benefits in Retailassortments , 1999 .

[19]  Steven Tadelis,et al.  Incentives Versus Transaction Costs: A Theory of Procurement Contracts , 2001 .

[20]  A. Tsay The Quantity Flexibility Contract and Supplier-Customer Incentives , 1999 .

[21]  Robert M. Fuhrer,et al.  Coordinating Investment, Production, and Subcontracting , 1999 .

[22]  Albert Y. Ha Supplier‐buyer contracting: Asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation , 2001 .

[23]  Charles J. Corbett,et al.  Stochastic Inventory Systems in a Supply Chain with Asymmetric Information: Cycle Stocks, Safety Stocks, and Consignment Stock , 2001, Oper. Res..

[24]  Evan L. Porteus,et al.  Selling to the Newsvendor: An Analysis of Price-Only Contracts , 2001, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[25]  Ernst Fehr,et al.  Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device , 2001 .

[26]  Gérard P. Cachon,et al.  Contracting to Assure Supply: How to Share Demand Forecasts in a Supply Chain , 2001, Manag. Sci..

[27]  George P. Baker,et al.  BRINGING THE MARKET INSIDE THE FIRM , 2001 .

[28]  Terry A. Taylor,et al.  Supply Chain Coordination Under Channel Rebates with Sales Effort Effects , 2002, Manag. Sci..

[29]  Brian Tomlin,et al.  Capacity Investments in Supply Chains: Sharing the Gain Rather Than Sharing the Pain , 2003, Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag..

[30]  Gérard P. Cachon Supply Chain Coordination with Contracts , 2003, Supply Chain Management.

[31]  Fangruo Chen,et al.  Information Sharing and Supply Chain Coordination , 2003, Supply Chain Management.

[32]  Morris A. Cohen,et al.  Measuring Imputed Cost in the Semiconductor Equipment Supply Chain , 2003, Manag. Sci..

[33]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Relational Incentive Contracts , 2003 .

[34]  Eric T. Bradlow,et al.  Promises and Lies: Restoring Violated Trust , 2004 .

[35]  D. D. de Quervain,et al.  The Neural Basis of Altruistic Punishment , 2004, Science.

[36]  T. Malone,et al.  Bringing the market inside. , 2004, Harvard business review.