Modeling the Democratic Peace as a Kantian Selection Process

Computational modeling is used to improve our understanding of how the democratic peace unfolds as a historical process in time and space. Whereas most of the conventional literature interprets the phenomenon as a constant and universal law operating at the state level, the author follows Immanuel Kant and treats democratic cooperation as an emergent macroprocess. The current study explores three causal mechanisms. First, strategic tagging introduces a way for democracies to select out like-minded cooperators. Second, regime-sensitive alliances enable democratic states to defend the gains of cooperation. Third, liberal collective security complements the liberal alignments. Based on these processes, it is possible to “grow” cooperative outcomes in an inhospitable geopolitical environment. Because tagging alone is insufficient, alliances, and sometimes even collective security, are necessary to produce perpetual peace. Such outcomes are characterized by high levels of spatial clustering.

[1]  R. Axelrod,et al.  The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration , 1998 .

[2]  Steve Chan,et al.  In Search of Democratic Peace: Problems and Promise , 1997 .

[3]  Thomas Risse-Kappen,et al.  Collective Identity in a Democratic Community: The Case of NATO , 1996 .

[4]  John F. Guilmartin,et al.  The Origin and Prevention of Major Wars: Domestic Politics and War , 1988 .

[5]  S. Walt,et al.  The Origins of Alliances , 2019 .

[6]  Robert Axelrod,et al.  Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions , 1985, World Politics.

[7]  J. Mearsheimer Back to the Future: Instability in Europe After the Cold War , 1990 .

[8]  K. Lindgren,et al.  Cooperation and community structure in artificial ecosystems , 1993 .

[9]  B. Russett,et al.  Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations , 2000 .

[10]  Jonathan Bendor,et al.  The Evolutionary Stability of Cooperation , 1997, American Political Science Review.

[11]  James Burk,et al.  Ballots and Bullets , 1999 .

[12]  J. Guilmartin,et al.  The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe. , 2012 .

[13]  David M. Rocke,et al.  Tacit bargaining, arms races, and arms control , 1990 .

[14]  P. Grim,et al.  Spatialization and greater generosity in the stochastic Prisoner's Dilemma. , 1996, Bio Systems.

[15]  Reinhard Wolf,et al.  Democratization and the Danger of War , 1995 .

[16]  M. Nowak,et al.  Tit for tat in heterogeneous populations , 1992, Nature.

[17]  John H. Holland,et al.  Hidden Order: How Adaptation Builds Complexity , 1995 .

[18]  Thomasine Cusack,et al.  Collective Security and State Survival in the Interstate System , 1994 .

[19]  David A. Lake Powerful Pacifists: Democratic States and War , 1992, American Political Science Review.

[20]  Wade L. Huntley Kant's Third Image: Systemic Sources of the Liberal Peace , 1996 .

[21]  A. Hurrell Kant and the Kantian paradigm in international relations , 1990, Review of International Studies.

[22]  H. Peyton Young,et al.  Individual Strategy and Social Structure , 2020 .

[23]  David Lazer,et al.  Emergent Actors in World Politics: How States and Nations Develop by Lars-Erik Cederman , 2001, J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul..

[24]  John M. Owen How Liberalism Produces Democratic Peace , 1994 .

[25]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The Evolution of Cooperation , 1984 .

[26]  I. Kant,et al.  The Metaphysics of Morals , 1997, The Ontology of Prejudice.

[27]  K. Gleditsch,et al.  War and Peace in Space and Time: The Role of Democratization , 2000 .

[28]  Christopher G. Langton,et al.  Artificial Life , 2019, Philosophical Posthumanism.

[29]  B A Huberman,et al.  Evolutionary games and computer simulations. , 1993, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[30]  Inis L. Claude,et al.  Power and International Relations , 1962 .

[31]  Wolf-dieter Eberwein The Future of International Warfare: Toward a Global Security Community? , 1995 .

[32]  Z. Maoz The Controversy over the Democratic Peace: Rearguard Action or Cracks in the Wall? , 1997, International Security.

[33]  C. Tilly Coercion, Capital, and European States, A.D. 990-1990 , 1990 .

[34]  Karl W. Deutsch,et al.  Social Mobilization and Political Development , 1961, American Political Science Review.

[35]  Eva Schaper,et al.  Kant's Political Writings , 1970 .

[36]  Kenneth N. Waltz,et al.  Theory of International Politics , 1979 .

[37]  Hendrik Spruyt,et al.  Institutional selection in international relations: state anarchy as order , 1994, International Organization.

[38]  R. Collins,et al.  Weberian Sociological Theory , 1986 .

[39]  R. Jervis Cooperation under the Security Dilemma , 1978, World Politics.

[40]  F. Fukuyama,et al.  The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics , 1997 .

[41]  Alexander Wendt,et al.  Anarchy is what states make of it: the social construction of power politics , 1992, International Organization.

[42]  Randolph M. Siverson,et al.  Birds of a Feather , 1991 .

[43]  G. Modelski Is world politics evolutionary learning? , 1990, International Organization.

[44]  Christopher Gelpi,et al.  Democratic Diversions , 1997 .

[45]  L. Cederman Back to Kant: Reinterpreting the Democratic Peace as a Macrohistorical Learning Process , 2001, American Political Science Review.

[46]  William R. Thompson,et al.  A Tale of Two Democratic Peace Critiques , 1997 .

[47]  Erik Gartzke,et al.  Political System Similarity And The Choice of Allies , 1996 .

[48]  Thomasine Cusack,et al.  Exploring Realpolitik , 1990 .

[49]  Karl W. Deutsch,et al.  Political Community And The North Atlantic Area , 1958 .

[50]  Joshua M. Epstein,et al.  Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom Up , 1996 .

[51]  Michael X Cohen,et al.  The Emergence of Social Organization in the Prisoner's Dilemma: How Context-Preservation and Other Factors Promote Cooperation , 1999 .