Participation costs can suppress the evolution of upstream reciprocity.

Indirect reciprocity, one of the many mechanisms proposed to explain the evolution of cooperation, is the idea that altruistic actions can be rewarded by third parties. Upstream or generalized reciprocity is one type of indirect reciprocity in which individuals help someone if they have been helped by somebody else in the past. Although empirically found to be at work in humans, the evolution of upstream reciprocity is difficult to explain from a theoretical point of view. A recent model of upstream reciprocity, first proposed by Nowak and Roch (2007) and further analyzed by Iwagami and Masuda (2010), shows that while upstream reciprocity alone does not lead to the evolution of cooperation, it can act in tandem with mechanisms such as network reciprocity and increase the total level of cooperativity in the population. We argue, however, that Nowak and Roch's model systematically leads to non-uniform interaction rates, where more cooperative individuals take part in more games than less cooperative ones. As a result, the critical benefit-to-cost ratios derived under this model in previous studies are not invariant with respect to the addition of participation costs. We show that accounting for these costs can hinder and even suppress the evolution of upstream reciprocity, both for populations with non-random encounters and graph-structured populations.

[1]  M. Tomassini,et al.  Social Dilemmas and Cooperation in Complex Networks , 2006 .

[2]  J Gómez-Gardeñes,et al.  Dynamical organization of cooperation in complex topologies. , 2007, Physical review letters.

[3]  M A Nowak,et al.  The dynamics of indirect reciprocity. , 1998, Journal of theoretical biology.

[4]  Sébastien Roch,et al.  Upstream reciprocity and the evolution of gratitude , 2007, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[5]  F. C. Santos,et al.  A new route to the evolution of cooperation , 2006, Journal of evolutionary biology.

[6]  O. Leimar,et al.  Evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity , 2001, Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences.

[7]  Karl Sigmund,et al.  The competition of assessment rules for indirect reciprocity. , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[8]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring , 1998, Nature.

[9]  Jun Tanimoto,et al.  Does “game participation cost” affect the advantage of heterogeneous networks for evolving cooperation? , 2010 .

[10]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  How should we define goodness?--reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.

[11]  W. Güth,et al.  Trust and reciprocity in the investment game with indirect reward , 2000 .

[12]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks , 2006, Nature.

[13]  M. Dufwenberg,et al.  Direct versus indirect reciprocity : An experiment , 2001 .

[14]  A. Isen,et al.  Positive affect, cognitive processes, and social behavior. , 1987 .

[15]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics , 1998 .

[16]  L. Stanca Measuring Indirect Reciprocity: Whose Back Do We Scratch? , 2009 .

[17]  M. Nowak Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation , 2006, Science.

[18]  P. Richerson,et al.  The evolution of indirect reciprocity , 1989 .

[19]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity , 2005, Nature.

[20]  G. Szabó,et al.  Evolutionary games on graphs , 2006, cond-mat/0607344.

[21]  R. D. Alexander The biology of moral systems , 1989 .

[22]  Martin A Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary games on cycles , 2006, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[23]  Karl Sigmund,et al.  The good, the bad and the discriminator--errors in direct and indirect reciprocity. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[24]  Karthik Panchanathan,et al.  A tale of two defectors: the importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. , 2003, Journal of theoretical biology.

[25]  Albert,et al.  Emergence of scaling in random networks , 1999, Science.

[26]  C. Hauert,et al.  Volunteering as Red Queen Mechanism for Cooperation in Public Goods Games , 2002, Science.

[27]  P. Taylor,et al.  Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics , 1978 .

[28]  D. DeSteno,et al.  Gratitude and Prosocial Behavior , 2006, Psychological science.

[29]  K. Sigmund The Calculus of Selfishness , 2010 .

[30]  W. Hamilton The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I. , 1964, Journal of theoretical biology.

[31]  L. Cavalli-Sforza,et al.  Assortment of encounters and evolution of cooperativeness. , 1982, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[32]  Naoki Masuda,et al.  Upstream reciprocity in heterogeneous networks. , 2009, Journal of theoretical biology.

[33]  D. Wilson A theory of group selection. , 1975, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[34]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary game dynamics with non-uniform interaction rates. , 2006, Theoretical population biology.

[35]  Francisco C. Santos,et al.  Population Structure Induces a Symmetry Breaking Favoring the Emergence of Cooperation , 2009, PLoS Comput. Biol..

[36]  N. Masuda Participation costs dismiss the advantage of heterogeneous networks in evolution of cooperation , 2007, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[37]  Daniel J. Rankin,et al.  Assortment and the Evolution of Generalized Reciprocity , 2009, Evolution; international journal of organic evolution.

[38]  Karl Sigmund,et al.  The logic of reprobation: assessment and action rules for indirect reciprocation. , 2004, Journal of theoretical biology.

[39]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  Global analyses of evolutionary dynamics and exhaustive search for social norms that maintain cooperation by reputation. , 2007, Journal of theoretical biology.

[40]  R. Trivers The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism , 1971, The Quarterly Review of Biology.

[41]  Sebastian Bonhoeffer,et al.  Evolution of cooperation by generalized reciprocity , 2005, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[42]  Mark E. J. Newman,et al.  The Structure and Function of Complex Networks , 2003, SIAM Rev..

[43]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary games and spatial chaos , 1992, Nature.

[44]  Michael Doebeli,et al.  A simple and general explanation for the evolution of altruism , 2009, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[45]  L. Berkowitz,et al.  AFFECTING THE SALIENCE OF THE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY NORM: EFFECTS OF PAST HELP ON THE RESPONSE TO DEPENDENCY RELATIONSHIPS. , 1964, Journal of abnormal psychology.

[46]  Jörgen W. Weibull,et al.  Evolutionary Game Theory , 1996 .

[47]  M. Taborsky,et al.  Generalized Reciprocity in Rats , 2007, PLoS biology.

[48]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Scale-free networks provide a unifying framework for the emergence of cooperation. , 2005, Physical review letters.

[49]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Graph topology plays a determinant role in the evolution of cooperation , 2006, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[50]  M. Taborsky,et al.  Contingent movement and cooperation evolve under generalized reciprocity , 2005, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[51]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The Evolution of Cooperation , 1984 .

[52]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Rock-scissors-paper game on regular small-world networks , 2004 .