Inefficiency and social exclusion in a coalition formation game: experimental evidence

This paper reports the results of experiments involving a 3-person coalition formation game with an ultimatum bargaining character. The grand coalition was always the efficient coalition decision, whereas the values of the 2-person coalitions are varied such that they lead to an efficiency loss in the range of 6.7 up to 30 percent. Furthermore, the 2-person coalition implies social exclusion, since the not chosen member always receives a payoff of zero. Consistent with results reported in the literature on 2- person ultimatum bargaining experiments, negative reciprocity (i.e. punishment of unfair offers) plays a crucial role in decision making. The hypothesis that selfishness and anticipated negative reciprocity by proposers together with actual negative reciprocal behavior of responders lead to inefficient outcomes and social exclusion is strongly supported by the data. It turns out that a huge majority of proposers choose the inefficient and unfair 2-person coalition. Proposer-induced efficiency losses vary between 5 and 20 percent, and one sixth to almost one third of the population is excluded from participation.

[1]  Akira Okada,et al.  The Efficiency Principle in Non-Cooperative Coalitional Bargaining , 2000 .

[2]  Akira Okada A Noncooperative Coalitional Bargaining Game with Random Proposers , 1996 .

[3]  A. Rubinstein Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model , 1982 .

[4]  Ralph L. Keeney,et al.  Wise choices : decisions, games, and negotiations , 1996 .

[5]  Debraj Ray,et al.  A noncooperative theory of coalitional bargaining , 1993 .

[6]  R. Selten A Noncooperative Model of Characteristic-Function Bargaining , 1988 .

[7]  J. Kagel,et al.  Handbook of Experimental Economics , 1997 .

[8]  Robert J. Aumann,et al.  Essays in game theory and mathematical economics in honor of Oskar Morgenstern , 1981 .

[9]  Colin F. Camerer,et al.  Outside Options and Social Comparison in Three-Player Ultimatum Game Experiments , 1995 .

[10]  Werner Güth,et al.  From ultimatum bargaining to dictatorship: An experimental study of four games varying in the degree of veto power , 1997 .

[11]  H. Kunzi,et al.  Lectu re Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems , 1975 .

[12]  D. Levine Modeling Altruism and Spitefulness in Experiments , 1998 .

[13]  Alvin E. Roth,et al.  Learning in High Stakes Ultimatum Games: An Experiment in the Slovak Republic , 1998 .

[14]  G. Harrison,et al.  An Experimental Evaluation of Weakest Link/Best Shot Models of Public Goods , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[15]  E. Fehr,et al.  Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: experimental evidence , 1997 .

[16]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The Evolution of Cooperation , 1984 .

[17]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[18]  A. Roth,et al.  Considerations of Fairness and Strategy: Experimental Data from Sequential Games , 1992 .

[19]  S. Zamir,et al.  Bargaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An Experimental Study , 1991 .

[20]  Matthew L. Spitzer,et al.  Entitlements, Rights, and Fairness: An Experimental Examination of Subjects' Concepts of Distributive Justice , 1985, The Journal of Legal Studies.

[21]  Martin Dufwenberg,et al.  A theory of sequential reciprocity , 2004, Games Econ. Behav..

[22]  Reciprocity, Inefficiency and Social Exclusion: Experimental Evidence , 2001 .

[23]  Descriptive Theories of Bargaining , 1990 .

[24]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  How Communication Links Influence Coalition Bargaining: A Laboratory Investigation , 2003, Manag. Sci..

[25]  J. Kagel,et al.  Tests of Fairness Models Based on Equity Considerations in a Three-Person Ultimatum Game , 2001 .

[26]  Klaus M. Schmidt,et al.  A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation , 1999 .

[27]  Arno Riedl,et al.  When Culture does not matter: Experimental Evidence from Coalition Formation Ultimatum Games in Austria and Japan , 1999 .

[28]  W. Güth,et al.  An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining , 1982 .

[29]  E. Fehr,et al.  Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? An Experimental Investigation , 1993 .

[30]  M. Rabin,et al.  UNDERSTANDING SOCIAL PREFERENCES WITH SIMPLE TESTS , 2001 .

[31]  Joyce E. Berg,et al.  Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History , 1995 .

[32]  M. Rabin Published by: American , 2022 .

[33]  E. Fehr,et al.  Gift Exchange and Reciprocity in Competitive Experimental Markets , 1995 .

[34]  W. Güth,et al.  Ultimatum bargaining behavior : a survey and comparison of experimental results , 1990 .

[35]  E. Damme,et al.  Information, Strategic Behavior, and Fairness in Ultimatum Bargaining: An Experimental Study. , 1998, Journal of mathematical psychology.

[36]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition , 2000 .

[37]  Ernst Fehr,et al.  Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device , 2001 .

[38]  Werner Güth,et al.  From Ultimatum Bargaining to Dictatorship—an Experimental Study of Four Games Varying in Veto Power , 1997 .

[39]  Andrew Schotter,et al.  A LABORATORY INVESTIGATION OF MULTI-PERSON RATIONALITY AND PRESENTATION EFFECTS , 1994 .

[40]  Matthew L. Spitzer,et al.  The Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Tests , 1982, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[41]  Gary E. Bolton A Comparative Model of Bargaining: Theory and Evidence , 1991 .

[42]  W. Güth,et al.  Two-Level Ultimatum Bargaining with Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study , 1996 .

[43]  R. Thaler,et al.  Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and Manners , 1995 .

[44]  Armin Falk,et al.  A Theory of Reciprocity , 2001, Games Econ. Behav..